Está en la página 1de 44

Did Adhering to the Gold Standard

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Reduce the Cost of Capital?


Ron Alquist and Benjamin Chabot

November 22, 2010

WP 2010-13
DidAdheringtotheGoldStandardReducetheCostofCapital?

RonAlquist
BankofCanada

BenjaminChabot
FederalReserveBankofChicagoandNBER

Abstract:AcommonlycitedbenefitofthepreͲWorldWarOnegoldstandardisthatitreduced
thecostofinternationalborrowingbysignalingacountry’’scommitmenttofinancialprobity.
Usinganewlyconstructeddatasetthatconsistsofmorethan55,000monthlysovereignbond
returns,wetestifgoldͲstandardadherencewasnegativelycorrelatedwiththecostofcapital.
ConditionalonUKriskfactors,wefindnoevidencethatthebondsissuedbycountriesoffgold
earnedsystematicallyhigherexcessreturnsthanthebondsissuedbycountriesongold.Our
resultsarerobusttoallowingbetastodifferacrossbondsissuedbycountriesoffͲandonͲgold;
toincludingproxiesthatcapturetheeffectoffiscal,monetary,andtradeshocksonthe
commitmenttogold;andtocontrollingfortheeffectofmembershipintheBritishEmpire.



Keywords:Goldstandard;sovereignborrowingcosts;countryriskpremium.

JELclassifications:F33;G15;N23.


Acknowledgements:WethankJeremyAtack,ChristianeBaumeister,CharlesCalomiris,WeiDong,
RobertLafrance,KimOosterlinck,GregorSmith,LindaTesar,andMarcWeidenmierforcommentsand
suggestions.Wealsothankseminarparticipantsatthe2006NBERSummerInstitute,theCenterfor
FinancialStudiesSummerSchool,andthe2008CanadianEconomicAssociationmeetingsforhelpful
comments.MaggieJimandRobPrechtprovidedfirstͲrateresearchassistance.

Theviewsexpressedinthepaperrepresenttheauthors’’ownandshouldnotbeattributedtoFederal
ReserveBankofChicago,TheFederalReserveSystemortheBankofCanada.

CorrespondingAuthor:RonAlquist,BankofCanada,234WellingtonStreet,Ottawa,ONK1A0G9.
Email:ralquist@bankofcanada.ca.
1.Introduction
Thegoldstandardbefore1914isgenerallyconsideredtobeaprimeexampleofanexchange
rateregime’’sabilitytoconfercredibilityonacountry’’smacroeconomicpolicy.The““goodͲ
housekeepingsealofapproval””interpretationofthegoldstandardpostulatesthatgold
convertibilityensuredthatthegovernmentactedconsistentlyovertime,sothatadherenceto
goldservedasasignaloffinancialprobity.Accordingtothisview,countriesthatalways
maintainedconvertibilityorsuspendeditonlyduringwidelyagreedͲuponcircumstances(such
aswar)shouldhavebeenrewardedwithlowerborrowingcosts.
Despiteitssharpprediction,economistshavereachedconflictingconclusionsaboutthe
effectofgoldͲstandardadherenceonsovereignborrowingcosts.Intheirseminalstudy,Bordo
andRockoff(1996)comparethecouponyields(couponͲpriceratios)ofsovereignbondsissued
byninecountriesandfindsubstantialcrossͲcountryvariationinpreͲWorldWarOneyields.
Theyattributetheyielddifferencestodifferingcommitmenttogold.Thesefindingsare
consistentwiththecountrystudiesofMartinͲAcena(1993)andSussmanandYafeh(2000),and
wereconfirmedinalargercrossͲsectionofcountriesbyObstfeldandTaylor(2003).The
reductioninborrowingcostsassociatedwithadheringtogoldisestimatedtobeabout30Ͳ40
basispointsperyear(BordoandRockoff1996;andObstfeldandTaylor2003)
Ontheotherhand,FergusonandSchularick(2006)findnoevidencethatthecapital
marketrewardedgoldͲstandardadherenceandconcludethatmembershipintheBritishEmpire
waskeytoreducingborrowingcosts.ClemensandWilliamson(2004)examinecapitalflows
ratherthanbondyieldsandpresentevidencethatgoldͲstandardadherencewasonly
marginallyimportantcomparedtofundamentaldeterminantsofcapitalproductivity.Flandreau
andZumer(2004)concludethatadheringtothegoldstandardhadanegligibleinfluenceon
couponyields,conditionalonothercovariatesintendedtocapturetheeffectoffiscaland
monetarypolicyonsovereignborrowingcosts.Theyarguethatinternationallendersfocused
onvariablesthatforecastacountry'sabilitytorepayitsexternaldebtandthattheseforecasts
assignedlittleweighttotheexchangeͲrateregime.MitchenerandWeidenmier(2009)compare
withinͲcountrycouponyieldsofbondswithandwithoutgoldclausesandconcludethatthe
internationalcapitalmarketplacedlittleweightongoldͲstandardadherence.

2
 Thecruxoftheempiricaldisagreementcanbetracedtodifferencesintheavailable
data.Incontrasttotoday,sovereignborrowersduringthegoldͲstandarderaissueddebtwith
differentmaturitiesandatinfrequentintervals.Asaresult,atypical19thcenturysovereign
borrowerhadonlyahandfulofmaturitiestradingatanygiventime,makingitimpossibleto
compareacrossͲsectionofbondswithmatchedmaturities.Tocomplicatemattersfurther,
mostcountriesissuedbondswithstochasticmaturityschedulesthatmakeitimpossibleto
computeyieldͲtoͲmaturityandpreventdirectcomparisonsofyieldsacrosscountries.
Datalimitationshaveforcedpastresearcherstoinferborrowingcostsbycomparingthe
couponyieldofbondsatdifferentpointsoftheyieldcurve.Typically,asinglerepresentative
bondischosenforeachcountrybasedonavailability,liquidity,ortheamountoutstanding.The
couponyieldisobservedforaslongaspossible,afterwhichanotherrepresentativebondis
chosen.Becausebondswiththesame(unobserved)discountratecanhaveverydifferent
couponyieldsattributabletodifferencesintimetomaturityorcouponamounts,thereisno
guaranteethattheobserveddifferencesinthecouponyieldofbondswithdifferentmaturities
actuallyareduetodifferencesintheexchangeͲrateregimeratherthanthetermstructureof
theborrower’’sexternaldebt.Inlightofthesechallenges,itisnotsurprisingthatauthorsusing
differentrepresentativebondshavearrivedatconflictingconclusions.
Becauseitisunlikelythataconsensuscanbereachedwiththeexistingdata,we
proposeatestofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisbasedonanewandmuchlargersample
ofrealizedholdingͲperiodreturns.Withover55,000bondreturns,thesizeofournewdataset
representsanalmost40ͲfoldincreaseinthecrossͲsectionofavailablebondprices.1Ourdata
setconsistsofeveryregularlyquotedsovereignbondfromtheofficialquotationlistofthe
LondonStockExchangebetween1870and1907.Weavoidthedifficultyofinferringdiscount
ratesfromthecouponyieldofbondswithdifferenttimestomaturitybycollectingmonthly
pricedataandcalculatingrealizedholdingͲperiodreturns.UsingholdingͲperiodreturnsisanew
waytomeasurethecostofcapitalintestsofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesis,butitisvery

1
Toourknowledge,thetwolargestprevioussamplesof19thcenturysovereignbondpricesarethedatasets
availablefromGlobalFinancialData(GFD)usedbyObstfeldandTaylor(2003)andtheoneconstructedby
FergusonandSchularick(2006).GFDcontains892annualobservationswhileFergusonandSchularick’’sdataset
contains1461annualobservations.

3
commoninassetͲpricingteststhattrytoaccountforcrossͲsectionaldifferencesinexpected
bondreturnstoexͲanteobservablecharacteristics.
Wefindthatadherencetothegoldstandarddidnotreducethecostofcapital.Acrossa
varietyofspecificationsandsamples,thereisnosystematiclinkbetweenacountryadheringto
goldandtheriskͲadjustedreturnofitssovereigndebt.ConditionalonBritishriskfactors,the
returnsofbondsissuedbycountriesonandoffgoldarestatisticallyindistinguishablefromone
another.Wealsoexaminealmost20,000bondreturnsfromcountriesthatswitchtheir
exchangerateregimeanddonotfindsystematicdifferencesinthesensitivityofthereturnsto
pervasiveriskfactorsacrossregimes.OurfindingscastdoubtuponthegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesisandsupporttheconclusionreachedbyFlandreauandZumer(2004)thatgoldͲ
standardadherencedidnothaveaneconomicallyimportanteffectonthecostofcapital.
Section2discussesthelogicofthegoldstandardasarepeatedgame.Section3
examinesthecloseparallelsbetweentestsofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisandassetͲ
pricingtestsdesignedtodetectdifferencesinmeanreturnsacrosssecurities.Section4
describestheempiricalspecification,methods,anddataweusetotestthegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesis.Section5reportstheresultsandasetofrobustnesstests.

2.TheGoldStandardasaRepeatedGame
BordoandKydland(1995)modelthegoldstandardasacrediblecommitmentmechanismthat
evolvedtoovercomethetimeͲinconsistencyproblemassociatedwithinternationalborrowing.
Borrowersandlendersintheinternationalcapitalmarketplayarepeatedgameinwhichthe
governmentchoosesamixofborrowing,taxation,andinflationtominimizethedeadweight
lossforagivenlevelofrevenue.Thegovernment’’sabilitytoprintmoneyandinflateawaythe
nominalvalueofexternaldebtcreatesanincentiveproblemwhenitonlycaresaboutthe
welfareofitsresidents(Bohn1991).Foreignlendersrecognizethedistortedincentivesofthe
borrowingcountryandareunwillingtolendfundswithoutacrediblecommitmentthatthe
governmentwillrepaytherealvalueofitsdebt.
Intherepeatedgame,agovernmentcanovercomethetimeͲinconsistencyproblemby
adoptinganeasyͲtoͲmonitorpolicythatpreventsitfromdevaluingitscurrency.ThegoodͲ

4
housekeepinghypothesispostulatesthatadherencetogoldservedassuchamechanism.The
goldͲstandardequilibriumstrategyconsistsofthegovernmentcommittingtocurrencystability
bystandingreadytoconvertlocalcurrencyintogoldondemand.Inresponse,theinternational
bondmarketrewardsthegovernmentthattiesitscurrencytogoldwithalowcostofcapital.
TheempiricalimplicationofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisisthattheinternationalcapital
marketassignedalowerprice,anddemandedcommensuratelyhigherexpectedreturns,to
bondsissuedbycountriesthatdidnotadheretothegoldstandard.
The““goodͲhousekeeping””repeatedgameequilibriumreliesonthecapitalmarket
collectivelyforgoingcurrentexpectedprofitstopunishgovernmentsthatleftgold.For
example,iftwodifferentcountriesissuebondswithidenticalexpectedcashflows,the
equilibriumpunishmentstrategyrequiresinvestorstoassigndifferentpricesifthecountries
havedifferingcommitmentstogold.Assigningdifferentpricestothesameexpectedcashflow
createsastatisticalarbitrageopportunity.Therefore,therepeatedgameequilibriumrequiresa
collectiveactionmechanismtopreventarbitrageͲseekinginvestorsfrompushingthepricesof
otherwiseidenticaloffͲandonͲgoldbondstogether.Largeinstitutionalinvestorswhowere
bothsufficientlypatienttoplaythepunishmentstrategyandlargeenoughtoinfluence
equilibriumprices,suchastheCouncilofForeignBondholdersandinvestmentbankswho
underwrotebondissues,weregoodcandidatestopunishcountriesthatabandonedthegold
standard.TheavailablearchivalevidencesuggeststhattheCouncilwaseffectiveatboth
organizinglenderswhenborrowersdefaultedandrenegotiatingwithlargeborrowerslike
Argentina,Brazil,andTurkey(MauroandYafeh2003).ThetestofthehypothesisthatoffͲgold
bondsearnedhigherriskͲadjustedreturnsthanonͲgoldbondsisadirectempiricaltestof
whethertheseorganizationsweresufficientlypowerfultopunishcheaters.

3.TestingtheGoodͲHousekeepingHypothesis
ThetheoryproposedbyBordoandKydlandmakesaclearprediction:Countrieswererewarded
withalowdiscountrateiftheymaintaingoldconvertibility.Butbonddiscountratesvaryfor
reasonsotherthanacountry’’sgoldͲstandardadherence,andanytestofthehypothesisneeds
tocontrolforotherdeterminantsofacountry’’sriskpremium.TraditionaltestsofthegoodͲ

5
housekeepinghypothesiscomparethecouponyieldofbondsoffͲandonͲgoldcontrollingfor
otherriskfactorsbyestimatingregressionsthatareverysimilartoassetͲpricingtestsdesigned
todetectcrossͲsectionaldifferencesinreturns,conditionalonotherpervasiveriskfactors.
Indeed,BordoandRockoffwritethattheirempiricalspecificationofthegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesisis““inspiredbythecapitalassetpricingmodel””(BordoandRockoff1996).The
empiricalspecificationsofselectedtestsofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisarereproduced
inTable1.
AllofthesetestsexaminetheeffectofgoldͲstandardadherenceonriskͲadjustedreturn
byformallytestingforashiftintheinterceptሺɷ ൏ Ͳሻofamodelthatcontrolsforother
determinantsofthesovereignriskpremium.Theregressiontestsareformulatedtodetecta
commondifferenceinthemeanriskͲadjustedcouponyieldbetweenonͲandoffͲgoldcountries.
 ThespecificationslistedinTable1areverysimilartofactormodelͲbasedassetpricing
teststhatcrossͲsectionalvariationinexͲanteobservablecharacteristicsgeneratesdifferences
inmeanexcessreturns.2Bothcontrolforriskusingfactormodelsandtestifanobservable
characteristicaffectsriskͲadjustedreturnbyexaminingcrossͲsectionaldifferencesinportfolio
intercepts.TraditionaltestsofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisandfactormodelbasedtests
arethusfullyconsistentwitheachanother.
HoldingͲperiodreturnsareanaturalwaytomeasuringborrowingcostswhenthe
numberofbondsistoosmalltoidentifytheyieldcurveorcomparecouponyieldsatmatched
maturities.LikecouponͲyield,holdingͲperiodreturnsarecorrelatedwiththeunobservable
discountrateandcanbeusedtoinferdifferencesinexpectedreturns(Campbell1995).Unlike
couponͲyield,holdingͲperiodreturnsincludeboththeexpectedcouponyieldandtheexpected
capitalgain.Manysovereignbondsduringthelate19thcenturytradedwellaboveorbelowpar,
andrationalinvestorssurelyexpectedcapitallossesorgainswhenpurchasingthesebonds.
Returnstakeaccountoftheseexpectedchanges.

 

2
Forexample,CornellandGreen(1991),FamaandFrench(1993)andEltonetal.(1995)

6
4.EmpiricalMethods

WeusetheholdingͲperiodreturnsofvalueͲweightedcountryportfoliostoaccountforboth
maturitymismatchandembeddedoptions.Foreachcountry,wecomputetheholdingͲperiod
returnonthevalueͲweightedportfolioofbondsoutstanding.IfcountryihasJbonds
outstandingattimet,thereturnofcountryi’’sportfoliois


(1)  ܴ௜௧ ൌ σ௝ୀଵ ‫ݓ‬௜௝௧ ൈ ܴ௜௝௧ 


where‫ݓ‬௜௝௧ isthemarketͲvalueweightofbondjincountryiattimet;ܴ௜௝௧ ൌ ሺܲ௜௝௧ ൅
‫ܥ‬௜௝௧ ሻȀܲ௜௝௧ିଵ isthegrossholdingͲperiodreturnofbondjincountryI;ܲ௜௝௧ isthepriceofthe
bondattimet;and‫ܥ‬௜௝௧ isthecouponpayment(ifany)betweentimetͲ1andtimet.Thereturn
andamountoutstandingofallofthebondsisdirectlyobservable,asiswhetherabondiscalled
andredeemedatpar(oranyothervalue).
WefocusonholdingͲperiodreturnsratherthancouponyieldbecausereturnsaccount
formaturitymismatchcausedbybothdifferencesinmaturityandembeddedoptions.Many
sovereignbondscontainedstochasticmaturitiesduetoclauses,suchasredemptionoptions
thatgavetheborrowertherighttorepaythebondatparbetweenpreͲspecifieddates;sinking
fundsthatcommittedtheborrowertoredeemannuallyafixedportionofthedebtoutstanding;
orlotteriesinwhichtheissuercontractedtoredeemafixedportionoftheoriginalissueatpar
viaannualdrawings.Iftwocountrieshadbondsthatmaturedatdifferentdates,differencesin
observedcouponͲyieldcouldbeduetoobservingdifferentpointsonidenticalyieldcurves
(termstructures)ratherthanactualdifferencesinyieldcurves.Ifthebondalsohasastochastic
maturitydate,themeasurementerrorbecomesmoreacute.
TheexistenceofembeddedoptionsbiasesthecouponͲyieldmeasurescommoninthe
goodͲhousekeepingliterature.TheseoptionscreatewhatFlandreauandZumer(2004)call
““conversionrisk””.FlandreauandZumer(2004)controlforconversionriskbycarefullyselecting
bondswithcouponratessuchthattheirconversionoptionthatarelikelytobefaroutͲofͲtheͲ
money.Thisstrategyminimizesthemeasurementerrorproblem,but,atleastwithourLondon

7
sample,comesatthecostofhavingtoexcludemanycountriesthatonlyhavebondswherethe
optionisinorclosetoinͲtheͲmoney.
PreͲpaymentriskisrareinmodernͲdaysovereignbondmarkets,butquitecommonthe
marketsformortgagebackedsecurities,realͲestateinvestmenttrusts,andcorporatebonds.
Studiesthatexaminethereturnsofthesesecuritiesfaceexactlythesameproblemthatweface
inourtestofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesis:Doesanobservabletraitexplaindifferencesin
expectedreturn?TheuseofholdingͲperiodreturnsandfactormodelsofthetypethatinspired
BordoandRockoff‘‘sspecificationarecommonlyusedtomeasuredifferencesinriskadjusted
returnsacrossbondportfolioswithdifferentmaturitiesandembeddedoptions.3Thus,using
holdingͲperiodreturnstomeasuresovereignborrowingcostsfacilitatesthecomparisonof
bondswithdifferent,possiblystochastic,maturitiesandtakesaccountofexpectedcapitalgains
andlosses.

4.1.LeveragedPortfolios
WetestthehypothesisthatexpectedreturnsdifferacrossexchangeͲrateregimebyforminga
leveragedportfoliothatmimicsthereturnassociatedwithpurchasingallbondsissuedby
countriesoffgoldandsellingshortallbondsissuedbycountriesongold.4Atthebeginningof
eachholdingperiod,allbondsareassignedeithertoanonͲgoldoroffͲgoldportfolio.Ifa
countryadoptsthegoldstandard,weremovethatcountry’’sbondsfromtheoffͲgoldportfolio
andaddittotheonͲgoldportfolioatthebeginningofthenextholdingperiod,andviceversa.If
thegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisistrue,theleveragedportfolioshouldearnapositiveriskͲ
adjustedreturn.
Weusecontemporaryandmodernsourcestodateeachcountry’’sgoldͲstandard
adherence.AdetailedlistofthesourcesisreportedinAppendix2.Incaseswhereitisdifficult
todeterminedejureversusdefactoadherencetothegoldstandard,wecodethecountryas

3
BondfactormodelsinthespiritofFamaandFrench(1993)andEltonetal.(1995)typicallyincludemarket,term
structure,anddefaultfactorssimilartoourstockmarket(market),Consol(termstructure)andcorporatebond
(default)factors.ThesemodelsareoftenusedtotestfordifferencesintheriskͲadjustedreturn(alpha)ofbond
portfoliosthathavedifferentmaturitiesandembeddedoptions.
4
Tobeclear,weformulatethetestinthiswaynotbecausewethinka19thcenturyinvestorformedaleveraged
portfolioofsovereignbondsbasedongoldͲstandardadherencebutbecausedoingsoallowsustotestfora
differenceinmeanreturnsacrossthetwoexchangeͲrateregimes.

8
adheringtogoldfromthedejureconvertibilitydate.Inmanycases,weareabletodategoldͲ
standardadherencequiteprecisely,identifyingthemonthandsometimeseventhedayon
whichacountryadoptedorabandonedconvertibility.Inthecaseswherewecanonlyidentify
theyearinwhichacountryadoptedthegoldstandard,wedategoldͲstandardadherencefrom
January1ofthatyear.
ItisimportanttostressthatbecauseofhowwedategoldͲstandardadherence,our
benchmarkregressionsarebiasedtowardfindingevidenceinfavorofthegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesis.TheLondoncapitalmarketmayhaveanticipatedswitchesingoldͲstandard
adherenceandrepricedbondsinresponsetothechangeinexpectations.Ifthegood
housekeepinghypothesisistrue,thebondsissuedbycountriesoffgoldthatswitchtobeingon
goldexperienceacapitalgainasthemarketrepricestheirbondsatalowerdiscountrate.Ifthe
marketanticipatestheswitchfromofftoon,thereturnsoftheoffgoldportfolioarehigheven
beforethedateofofficialconvertibility.Similarly,thebondsissuedbycountriesongoldthat
switchoffexperienceacapitallossasthemarketrepricestheirbondsatahigherdiscountrate.
Again,ifthemarketanticipatessuchaswitch,thereturnsoftheonͲgoldportfolioareloweven
beforethecountryofficialabandonsconvertibility.Thus,thereturnsoftheoffͲgoldportfolio
arebiasedupwardbecauseofourdatingprocedurewhilethereturnsoftheonͲgoldportfolio
arebiaseddownward.Thetwoeffectsbiasthereturnsoftheleveragedportfolioupward.By
sortingbondsintooffͲandonͲgoldportfoliosandusingthisdatingprocedure,weextendthe
goodͲhousekeepinghypothesiseveryadvantageintheempiricaltest.5

4.2.EmpiricalSpecification
Weformaleveragedportfoliobycomputingthereturnsofaportfoliothatislonginthebonds
issuedbycountriesoffgoldandshortinthebondsissuedbycountriesongold.Ifthetwo
portfolioswereequallyriskyandthemarketpunishedbondsissuedbycountriesoffgold,this
strategywouldhavegeneratedpositiveexcessreturns.

5
Inanearlydraft,wecontrolledforanticipationeffectsbyformingperfectͲforesightportfolios.Weassignedbonds
totheoffͲandonͲgoldportfoliosuptotwoyearsbeforetheactualchangeinstatusoccurred.Ourconclusionthat
goldͲstandardadherencedidnotaffectsovereignborrowingcostsisrobusttothisalternativecodingscheme.
Theseresultsareavailableuponrequest.

9
 Thekeywordsare““equallyrisky””.Investorsduringthelate19thcenturyalmostsurely
demandedcompensationforrisksbeyondthoseembodiedingoldͲstandardadherence.If
exposuretootherriskfactorsdifferedacrossportfolios,differencesinrealizedreturnmaybe
duetoexposuretotheotherrisksandnotexclusivelyduetodifferencesingoldͲstandard
adherence.
Wecontrolforriskwithafactorpricingmodelthatcomparesthereturnofatest
portfoliotothatofasimilarlyriskyportfolioofBritishfinancialassets.Weestimatethe
regression

(2) ܴ௜௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൌ ߙ௜ ൅ ߚଵ ൫ܴ௖௢௡ǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߚଶ ൫ܴௌெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߚଷ ൫ܴ஻ெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߝ௧ 

whereܴ௜௧ isthetimetreturnofportfolioi;ܴ௖௢௡ǡ௧ isthetimetreturnontheUKgovernment
consol;ܴௌெǡ௧ isthereturnonthevalueͲweightedportfolioofallBritishequitiesattimet;and
ܴ஻ெǡ௧ isthevalueͲweightedportfolioofUKcorporatebonds.WeusetheLondonbanker’’sbill
rateasaproxyfortheriskͲfreerateܴ௙௧ .
ߙ௜ iscalledJensen’’salphaafterJensen(1967),whoproposedusingittomeasurea
portfolio’’sreturncontrollingforrisk.Alphameasuresthedifferencebetweenportfolioi’’s
returnandthereturnoftheportfolioofBritishsecuritieswithpercentageweightsߚଵ invested
intheUKgovernmentconsol,ߚଶ investedinthevalueͲweightedUKstockmarketportfolio,ߚଷ 
investedinthevalueͲweightedBritishbondmarketportfolioandͳ െ ߚଵ െ ߚଶ െ ߚଷ investedin
theLondonbanker’’sbill.
Weestimatetheexcessreturnoftheleveragedportfoliowiththeregressionequation:

(3) ܴ௢௙௙ǡ௧ െ ܴ௢௡ǡ௧ ൌ ߙ ൅ ߚ෨ଵ ൫ܴ௖௢௡ǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߚ෨ଶ ൫ܴௌெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߚ෨ଷ ൫ܴ஻ெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߝ௧ 

whereߚ෨௞ ൌ ߚ෨௢௙௙ǡ௞ െ ߚ෨௢௡ǡ௞ byconstruction.Thebetasoftheleveragedportfolioinequation(3)
areequaltothedifferenceinthesensitivitiesoftheoffͲgoldandonͲgoldportfoliosto
fluctuationsintheUKriskfactors.AtestofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisamountstothe
testthatalphaisgreaterthanzero.

10
Anadvantageofthistestisthatitaddressestheproblemthatcountriesdidnotleave
goldrandomly.Ifacountrywantedtoremainongoldbutwasforcedoffduetoanegative
businessͲcycleshock,weneedtodistinguishbetweenexcessreturnsduetoexposureto
businessͲcycleriskandtherepeatedgamepunishment.IfbusinessͲcycleshocksarecorrelated
acrosscountries,UKinvestorscouldhavelegitimatelydemandhigherexpectedreturnsas
compensationforbearinggreaterbusinessͲcyclerisk.Inthiscase,thegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesiscouldbefalsebutthereturnsofthebondsissuedbycountriesongoldwouldbe
lowerbecausetheywerelessexposedtoBritishbusinessͲcyclerisk.Bycomparingforeign
returnstothiscontrolgroupofsimilarlyriskyUKsecurities,wedisentanglethetwoeffectsand
cantestifinvestorsdemandedapremiumduetogoldͲstandardadherenceorbusinessͲcycle
risk.

4.3.Data
ThesemethodsnecessarilyrequiremonthlyreturndatafromalargecrossͲsectionofsovereign
bonds.WecollectasampleofsovereignandcolonialbondstradingontheLondonStock
Exchangebetween1870and1907.Ourdatasetconsistsofthebidandaskpricesandcoupon
paymentsforeveryforeigngovernmentbondregularlyquotedontheExchange.Thedata
representabroadcrossͲsectionofbondsissuedbycountriesbothonandoffgold(Figure1).
Thepricesaresampledevery28ͲdaysfromtheofficialFridayquotationlistpublishedinthe
MoneyMarketReviewandtheEconomist.6Weusethepriceandcoupondatatocomputea
timeseriesof28ͲdayholdingͲperiodreturnscorrectedforsovereigndefaults.7Appendix1
containsmoreinformationabouttheunderlyingdata.

4.4.SampleofCountries
Inadditiontothechallengesassociatedwithconsistentlymeasuringthesovereigncostof
capitalduringthelate19thcentury,apossibleexplanationforthelackofconsensusamong

6
Theholdingperiodis28ͲdaysbecauseoursourcespublishedtheLondonStockExchangepublishedofficialbid
andaskpriceseveryFriday.Wesampledthemevery4weeks.
7
WeusetheCouncilofForeignBondholders,Winkler(1933),Suter(1990),anddefaultdataprovidedbyObstfeld
andTaylor(2003)todateperiodsofdefault.

11
previoustestsofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisisthateachstudyusesadifferentsample.
Sinceoursampleofcountriesspansthoseconsideredinpreviousstudies,wecanexaminethe
effectofvaryingsamplecountries.Weconductourtestsonourfullsampleofcountriesaswell
asonsubsamplescorrespondingtothoseusedinBordoandRockoff(1996),Bordoand
Schwartz(1999),ObstfeldandTaylor(2003),andFlandreauandZumer(2004).Thecountriesin
thesesubsamplesarelistedinAppendix2.

4.5.CountryWeights
Itisalsoimportanttoguardagainstthepossibilitythatourconclusionsaredrivenbyoutliers.
Somecountrieshavemuchlargerbondissuesthanothersandanyconclusionsshouldberobust
toourweightingscheme.Toaddressthisproblem,weformbothvalueͲweightedandequally
weightedportfolios.ThevalueͲweightedportfolioweightseachbondbyitsmarketvalue.For
example,ifthemarketvalueofallArgentinebondsistentimesthatofDanishbonds,the
returnsofArgentinebondsreceivetentimestheweightofreturnsofDanishbondsinthe
valueͲweightedportfolio.Thus,weightingreturnsbythemarketvalueofthedebtoutstanding
weightslargebondsissuesmoreheavily.Theequallyweightedportfolioexaminesiflarge
borrowersdriveourconclusions;itconsistsofindividualcountryportfolios.8Ifthereare
ܰcountriesinthesample,thereturnofeachcountryportfolioreceivesaweightofͳΤܰ.This
weightingschememinimizestheeffectofthereturnsofbondsissuedbylargeborrowers.

5.EmpiricalResults
Table2reportstheindividualregressionresultsfortheoffͲandonͲgoldvalueͲandequally
weightedportfolios.Italsoreportstheregressionresultsfortheleveragedportfolioinequation
(3)thatislongtheoffͲgoldportfolioandshorttheonͲgoldportfolio.Thetableshowsthatthe
BritishfactormodeldoeswellinaccountingforthevariationinoffͲandonͲgoldportfolio
returns.TheadjustedRͲsquaredstatisticsarerespectableformonthlydata––between10Ͳ20%.
WhenoneformstheleveragedportfoliobytakingthedifferencebetweentheoffͲandonͲgold
portfolios,theRͲsquaredstatisticsarelow,whichsuggeststhatthereturnsfromtheleveraged

8
EachcountryportfolioisitselfvalueͲweighted.

12
portfolioareapproximatelywhitenoise.Thisfindingiswhatoneexpectsunderthenull
hypothesisthatthegoldstandardwasnotadeterminantofsovereignborrowingcosts.Sorting
bondsintooffͲandonͲgoldportfoliosshouldnotgeneratesystematicallyhigherreturns,after
controllingfortheUKmarketfactors.
 Unconditionally,thedifferencebetweenthemeanreturnofoffͲgoldandonͲgoldbonds
was1.4Ͳ1.6%peryear,dependingontheweightingscheme.Thisevidenceseemstosuggestthe
presenceofagoldpremium:OffͲgoldbondspaidhigherreturnstoinduceinvestorstohold
thembecausetheywereperceivedtoberiskier.Butprojectingthereturnsonthemarket
factorsshowsthatthedifferenceinriskͲadjustedreturns,measuredbythealphas,are
economicallysmall,statisticallyinsignificant,andhasthesignoppositetothatpredictedbythe
goodͲhousekeepinghypothesis.
 ThebetasobtainedfromtheleveragedportfolioindicatethattheoffͲgoldbond
portfolioismoresensitivetofluctuationsintheUKgovernmentconsolindexandtheBritish
corporatebondindex.Thisevidenceindicatesthatthehigherunconditionalmeanreturnofthe
offͲgoldportfoliocomparedtotheonͲgoldportfolioisattributabletotheportfolio’’sgreater
exposuretotheriskassociatedwithfluctuationsintheUKriskfactors.Thus,goinglongon
bondsissuedbycountriesoffgoldandshortingbondsissuedbycountriesongoldwouldhave
generatedpositivereturns,buttheexcessreturnsrepresentedcompensationforbearingmore
riskassociatedwithfluctuationsintheUKmarketfactorsratherfailingtoadheretothegold
standard.
Toexaminethesensitivityofthisconclusiontochangingthesample,Table3reportsthe
regressionresultsforleveragedoffͲgoldminusonͲgoldportfoliosusingdifferentsubsamplesof
countries.Dependingonthesample,sovereignoffͲgoldbondsgeneratedanaveragereturn
between1.6Ͳ2.5%higherperyearthanthereturngeneratedbybondsongold.Again,the
excessreturnisprimarilyattributabletodifferencesinexposuretobusinessͲcycleriskrather
thanmarketpunishmentfornotadheringtogold.Oncewecontrolformarketriskby
comparingtheleveragedportfoliostosimilarlyriskyBritishsecurities,theexcessreturns
vanish.Thealphasoftheleveragedportfoliosdecreaseinsizeand,inallcases,arenot
statisticallydifferentfromzero.Intwooutofthefivecountrysamples,thesignofthealphas

13
contradicttheempiricalimplicationofthegoodͲhousekeepinghypothesisinthatthealphasare
negative.InboththefullsampleandtheObstfeldͲTaylorsample,offͲgoldbondsearnedsmaller
riskͲadjustedreturnsthanonͲgoldbonds.
ThebetasinPanelAarepositive,withonlyoneexception.Ingeneral,theoffͲgold
portfolioismoresensitivetomovementsinthereturnsofUKgovernmentconsol,stock,and
corporatebondindicesthantheonͲgoldportfolios,suggestingthatthehigherunconditional
returnsassociatedwithholdingtheoffͲgoldbondswerecompensationforbearingrisk.UK
investorsdemandedapremiumtobearthisadditionalrisk,butitdidnotreflectpunishmentfor
abandoninggold.ThatthealphasareclosetozeroimpliesthataportfolioofBritishsharesand
bondswiththesameexposuretotheUKindiceswouldgeneratestatisticallyidenticalreturns.
BecausetheUKsecuritieswerenotbeingpunishedforviolatingtherulesofthegoldstandard,
theaverageexcessreturniscompensationforbearingbusinessͲcyclerisk.
 ThealphasreportedinTable3indicatethatportfoliosselectedbasedongoldͲstandard
adherencedonotoutperformportfoliosofUKsecuritieswiththesameexposuretobusinessͲ
cyclerisk.However,atestthatalphaequalszeroisajointtestofthegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesisandtheriskandreturnmodelimpliedbytheexcessreturnregression.Tobecertain
thatthesmallalphasarenotduetomodelmisspecification,wecomparethealphasofthe
leveragedportfoliostothealphabasedonselectingbondsrandomly.
ExpectedalphawillequalzeroiftheBritishportfoliosdoagoodjobofcapturing
consumptionrisk.Butifthemodelismisspecified,theexpectedalphaofarandomportfoliowill
bedifferentfromzero.Ourconcernisamisspecifiedmodelinwhicharandomportfoliowould
havenegativealpha.Inthatcase,theportfolioselectedusinggoldͲstandardadherencecould
haveanalphastatisticallyindistinguishablefromzeroandyetstillsignificantlyoutperform
randomlyselectedportfolios.ThisfindingwouldcastdoubtonthenullhypothesisthatgoldͲ
standardadherencedoesnotmatterforsovereignborrowingcosts.
Toaddressthispossibility,wecomparethereturnsgeneratedbytheleveragedgold
portfoliotoportfoliosselectedatrandom.ForeachsubsampleinTable3,wecomputeexcess
returnportfoliosbyrandomlyassigningthesamesampleofsecuritiestooneoftwoportfolios.
BondsareassignedinthesameproportionastheproportionofgoldͲstandardadherence.We

14
compute1000randomportfoliosandreporttheproportionoftimestheportfolioselected
usingthegoldstandardcriterionearnsahigherexcessreturnthanaportfolioselectedat
random.
Forexample,inthevalueͲweightedBordoͲRockoffsampleofsovereignbonds,56%of
theobservedreturnswerereturnsofbondsonthegoldͲstandard.Wecomputeanexcess
returnportfoliofromthesamesampleofcountriesbyrandomlybuying44%ofthebondseach
periodandshortingtheother56%.Wethencalculatetherandomportfolio’’salphaand
compareittothealphaofthegoldͲsortedportfolio.Werepeattherandomselection1000
times.Theresultis1000samplealphascorrespondingtotheriskͲadjustedreturnof1000
randomlyselectedportfolios.Bycomparingthenumberoftimesthattheleveragedportfolio
generatedpositiveexcessreturnswiththenumberoftimesthatarandomlyselectedportfolio
generatedpositiveexcessreturn,weareabletoseewhethersortingbondsbygoldͲstandard
adherenceresultsinhigherreturnsthanonewouldexpectfromsortingbondsintoportfolios
randomly.
Table3reportstheproportionoftimestheleveragedgoldͲsortedportfoliosbeat
portfoliosformedatrandom,orwhatwecallthe““successrate””.Theresultsareconsistentwith
theconclusionthatgoldͲstandardadherencedidnotmatterfortheexcessreturnsofsovereign
bonds.Inthefullsample,sortingsovereignbondsintovalueͲweightedportfoliosbasedongold
wouldhaveearnedgreaterexcessreturnsthansortingbondsrandomlyonly24.1%ofthetime.
Althoughthesuccessrateexceeds50%fortheBordoͲRockoffandFlandreauͲZumersamples,it
islessthan50%fortheObtsfeldͲTaylorsample.TheObstfeldͲTaylorsamplecontainsmore
countriesthantheBordoͲRockoffandFlandreauͲZumersamplesbutfewerthanarecontained
inthefullsample,indicatingthatsomeofthedisagreementabouttheeffectofgoldon
borrowingcostsmaybeattributabletothesetofcountriesbeingstudied.Overall,portfolios
selectedbygoldͲstandardadherencedonobetterthanportfoliosselectedatrandom.
Takentogether,thesepiecesofevidenceallpointinthesamedirection.Differencesin
bondreturnsrepresentedcompensationforexposuretoBritishriskfactorsanddidnotreflecta
goldpremium.


15
5.1.RobustnessCheck:GoldͲStandardAdherenceandBetas
Differencesbetweenthereturnsofbondsissuedbycountriesongoldandthoseissuedby
countriesoffgoldappeartobeexplainedbydifferencesintheirbetas.Thefindingthatthe
betasdifferwithgoldͲstandardadherenceisnotnew.Forexample,BordoandRockoff(1996)
andObstfeldandTaylor(2003)bothobservethatthecountries’’marketbetasappeartovary
withgoldͲstandardadherence.Neithersetofauthorsformallytestsfordifferencesinthebetas
byallowingthemtovarywithgoldͲstandardadherence,butbothpointoutthatcountrieson
goldtendtohavesmallerbetasthanthoseoffgoldovertheirrespectivesamples.9Thus,itis
possiblethatgoldͲstandardadherenceandthebetasarecorrelatedwithoneanother.Inthat
case,adheringtogoldcouldreducethecostofcapitalbyreducingthebetaofacountry’’s
bonds.Theinternationalcapitalmarketmayhaveviewedbondsissuedbycountriesongoldas
lesssensitivetobusinessͲcycleriskthanthoseissuedbycountriesoffgold,sothatacountry
couldloweritscostofcapitalbyadheringtogold.
 Toexaminethispossibility,weestimatetheequationforthesubsetofourindividual
bondsthatchangetheirgoldstatus:

(4)
ܴ௜௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൌ ߙ௜ ൅ ߚଵ ൫ܴ௖௢௡ǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߚଶ ൫ܴௌெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߚଷ ൫ܴ஻ெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൅ ߜଵ ൫ܴ௖௢௡ǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯
ൈ ‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ ൅ ߜଶ ൫ܴௌெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൈ ‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ ൅ ߜଷ ൫ܴ஻ெǡ௧ െ ܴ௙௧ ൯ ൈ ‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ ൅ ߝ௜௧ 

whereallofthevariablesaredefinedasbefore;and‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ isaninteractiondummyvariable
equalto1iftheissuingcountryisongoldattimet.Theregressionproducesthreeinteraction
coefficientsequaltothedifferencebetweenthebetaongoldandthebetaoffgold.
 Toensurethatdifferencesinthethreebetasareidentified,weneedasetofcountries
whosebondstradewhiletheissuingcountryisbothonandoffgold.Ourdatasetcontains86
suchbonds.Weestimate86separatetimeseriesregressionswhichresultin258(ൌ ͵ ൈ ͺ͸)
interactioncoefficients.Figure2showsthehistogramofthetͲstatisticsfromtheinteraction

9
Inaddition,FergusonandSchularick(2006)findthatdifferencesinmeancouponyieldsbetweenEmpireandnonͲ
EmpirebondsdisappearwhentheycontrolformarketriskandthatthebetasofEmpirebondsaresmallerthanthe
betasofnonͲEmpirebonds.

16
coefficients.Thedistributionofinteractioncoefficientsissymmetricandcenteredonzero.15
ofthe258(5.8%)arestatisticallydifferentfromzeroatthe5%significanceleveland22(8.5%)
atthe10%significancelevel.UsingtheSimes(1986)modifiedBonferronitest,wecannotreject
thejointnullhypothesisthatallinteractioncoefficientarejointlyequaltozero.Whilethe
differenceinreturnsbetweentheoffͲandonͲgoldportfolioscanbeexplainedbydifferencesin
thebetas,thedifferencesinbetasdonotappeartobeattributabletogoldͲstandard
adherence.TheresultiswhatonewouldexpectifgoldͲstandardadherencehadnoeffecton
thecostofcapital.

5.2.SensitivityAnalysis
5.2.1.Fiscal,Monetary,andTradeControls
GoldͲstandardadherencemayactasaproxyforfollowingprudentfiscalandmonetarypolicies,
asproposedbyFlandreauandZumer(2004).Itisthereforeimportanttotestifgoldreduces
sovereignborrowingcosts,conditionaloncovariatesthatcapturetherisksassociatedwith
weakfiscalandmonetarypolicies.Inaddition,otherstudiesofthegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesishaveincludedmacroeconomiccontrolslikethelaggedinflationrateandthedeficitͲ
GDPratiotodetectdeviationsfromthecommitmenttogold(BordoandRockoff1996;and
ObstfeldandTaylor2003).Includingcovariatestocapturetheserisksinthefactormodelalso
facilitatescomparisonwiththeseotherstudies.
Wecontrolforfiscal,monetary,andtradeshocksbyformingfactorͲmimickingportfolios
usingdataonthedeficitͲGDPratio,annualinflation,andtheexportͲGDPratiothatareavailable
for22countries.10Columns1Ͳ3inTable4showthatincludingthefactorͲmimickingportfolios
hasnoeffectontheconclusions.TheoffͲgoldminusonͲgoldportfolioalpharemains
indistinguishablefromzero.

10
FamaandFrench(1995)andDanielandTitman(1997)useanidenticalproceduretoevaluatetheeffectofsize
andvaluecharacteristicsonequityreturns.WeformthefactorͲmimickingportfoliosinthefollowingway.First,at
thebeginningofeachyearwesortcountriesintothreemutuallyexclusivecategories(high,medium,andlow)
basedonthevalueofeachcharacteristic.ThehighcategorycontainsthetoponeͲthirdofcountrieswhilethelow
categorycontainsthebottomoneͲthirdofcountries.Second,weusethebondsissuedbycountriesinthehighand
lowcategoriestoformvalueͲweightedportfolios.Third,wecomputeafactorͲmimickingportfoliobyforminga
leveragedhighminuslow(HML)portfoliosforeachofthethreemacroeconomicvariables.Forexample,thedeficit
HMLportfolioistheportfolioformedbybuyingsovereignbondsinthetoponeͲthirdofthedeficitͲGDPcategory
andsellingshortthesovereignbondsinthebottomoneͲthirdofthedeficitͲGDPcategory.

17

5.2.2.ControllingfortheEmpireEffect
Accominottietal.(2010)demonstratethatdummyvariablesregressiontestsoftheeffectof
membershipintheBritishEmpireonborrowingcostsarepotentiallymisspecified.Theyshow
thatpoolingbondsissuedbyBritishcolonieswithbondsissuedbyindependentcountriescan
leadtobiasedparameterestimatesandmisleadinginferencesinyieldͲspreadregressions.To
ensurethatourconclusionsabouttheeffectofgoldstandardadherenceonsovereign
borrowingcostsarerobust,weexcludetheBritishcoloniesfromtheportfoliosortsandreͲrun
ourtestonthesubsetofbondsthatwereissuedbyindependentcountries.
 Columns4Ͳ6inTable4reportthealphasandbetasobtainedfromformingoffͲandonͲ
goldportfoliosforthesetofindependentcountriesinoursample(i.e.,bondsnotissuedby
Britishcolonies).TheunconditionaldifferencebetweenonͲgoldandoffͲgoldbondreturns
shrinkswhenweexcludecolonialbondsandtheriskͲadjustedreturnsoftheoffͲgoldminusonͲ
goldportfoliodecreases.Importantly,themainresultthatgoldͲstandardadherenceis
uncorrelatedwithriskͲadjustedreturnisunaffectedwhenthecolonialbondsareomitted.

6.Conclusion
Usingacomprehensivenewdataset,wefindnoevidenceinfavorofthegoodͲhousekeeping
hypothesis.Althoughthebondsissuedbycountriesoffofgolddidearnhigherunconditional
returnsthanthebondsofcountriesongold,thisdifferencevanishesoncewecontrolfor
exposuretocommonriskfactors.Thisevidencerejectsthegoodhousekeepinghypothesisand
isconsistentwithFlandreauandZumer’’s(2004)findingthattheeffectofgoldstandard
adherenceonborrowingcostsvanisheswiththeinclusionofotherexplanatoryvariablesthat
capturedefaultrisk.
Thisconclusionisrobust.WefindnoevidenceofagoldͲstandardeffectinanyofthesub
samplesofcountriesincludedinpreviousstudies.Theresultsarenotsensitivetoaddingfiscal,
monetary,andtradecontrolstoaccountformacroeconomicshocksthatcanaffectthe
commitmenttogold.Finally,omittingtheBritishcoloniesfromthebenchmarkspecification
doesalterourconclusions.

18
Theseresultsshedlightontheperceivedbenefitsoftheclassicalgoldstandardin
particularandfixedexchangeͲrateregimesmoregenerally.Awidelycitedbenefitofthegold
standard––arguablythemostcrediblefixedexchangeͲrateregimeinmodernhistory––isthatit
reducedborrowingcosts.WhateverotherbenefitsacrediblyfixedexchangeͲrateregime
confersonitsadherents,theinternationalcapitalmarketdidnotrewardgoldͲstandard
adherencewithalowercostofcapital.

19
References
Accominotti,Olivier,MarcFlandreau,andRiadRezzik.““TheSpreadofEmpire:Clioandthe
MeasurementofColonialBorrowingCosts.””EconomicHistoryReviewforthcoming.

Bohn,Henning.““TimeConsistencyofMonetaryPolicyintheOpenEconomy.””Journalof
InternationalEconomics30,no.3Ͳ4(1991):249Ͳ266.

Bordo,MichaelD.,andAnnaJ.Schwartz.““TheOperationoftheSpecieStandard:Evidencefor
CoreandPeripheralCountries:1880Ͳ1990.””InTheGoldStandardandRelatedRegimes:
CollectedEssays,editedbyMichaelD.Bordo,238Ͳ317.NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress,
1999.

Bordo,MichaelD.,andFinnKydland.““TheGoldStandardasaRule.””ExplorationsinEconomic
History32,no.4(1995):423Ͳ464.

Bordo,MichaelD.,andHughRockoff.““TheGoldStandardasaGoodͲhousekeepingSealof
Approval.””JournalofEconomicHistory56,no.2(1996):389Ͳ428.

Clemens,MichaelA.andJeffreyG.Williamson.““WealthBiasintheFirstGlobalCapitalMarket
Boom,1870Ͳ1913.””EconomicJournal114,no.495(2004):304Ͳ337.

Campbell,John.““SomeLessonsfromtheYieldCurve.””JournalofEconomicPerspectives9,no.3
(1995):129Ͳ152.

Cornell,BradfordandKevinGreen.““TheInvestmentPerformanceofLowͲGradeBondFunds””
JournalofFinance,(1991)46,29––48

Daniel,KentandSheridanTitman.““EvidenceontheCharacteristicsofCrossͲSectionalVariation
inCommonStockReturns””,JournalofFinance(1997)52,1——33

Elton,EdwinJ.,MartinJ.Gruber,ChristopherR.Blake.““FundamentalEconomicVariables,
ExpectedReturns,andBondFundPerformance.””JournalofFinance50(1995):1229Ͳ1256.

Fama,EugeneF.andKennethR.French.““CommonRiskFactorsintheReturnsonStocksand
Bonds.””JournalofFinancialEconomics33(1993):3Ͳ56.

Fama,EugeneF.,andKennethR.French.““SizeandBookͲtoͲMarketFactorsinEarningsand
Returns.””JournalofFinancialEconomics50,no.1(1995):131Ͳ155.

20

Ferguson,Niall,andMoritzSchularick.““TheEmpireEffect:TheDeterminantsofCountryRiskin
theFirstAgeofGlobalization,1880Ͳ1913.””JournalofEconomicHistory66,no.2(2006):283Ͳ
312.

Flandreau,Marc,andFredericZumer.TheMakingofGlobalFinance,1880Ͳ1913.
Paris:OrganizationforEconomicCooperationandDevelopment,2004.

Jensen,MichaelC.““ThePerformanceofMutualFundsinthePeriod1945Ͳ1964.””Journalof
Finance23,no.2(1967),389Ͳ416.

MartinͲAcena,Pablo.““SpainDuringtheClassicalGoldStandardYears,1880Ͳ1914.””InMonetary
RegimesinTransition,editedbyMichaelD.BordoandForrestCapie,135Ͳ172.NewYork:
CambridgeUniversityPress,1993.

Mauro,Paolo,andYishayYafeh.““TheCorporationofForeignBondholders.””IMFWorkingPaper
No.03/107,Washington,D.C.,May2003.

Mitchener,Kris,andMarcD.Weidenmier."AreHardPegsEverCredibleinEmergingMarkets?
EvidencefromtheClassicalGoldStandard,"NBERWorkingPapers15401,NationalBureauof
EconomicResearch.

Obstfeld,Maurice,andAlanM.Taylor.““SovereignRisk,Credibility,andtheGoldStandard:
1870Ͳ1913versus1925Ͳ31.””EconomicJournal113,no.487(2003):241Ͳ275.

Simes,S.John.““AnImprovedBonferroniProcedureforMultipleTestsofSignificance.””
Biometrika73,no.3(1986):751Ͳ754.

Sussman,Nathan,andYishayYafeh.““Institutions,Reforms,andCountryRisk:
LessonsfromJapaneseGovernmentDebtintheMeijiPeriod.””JournalofEconomicHistory60,
no.2(2000):442Ͳ467.

Suter,Christian.SchuldenzykleninderdrittenWelt:Kreditaufnahme,Zahlungskrisenund
SchuldenregelungenperiphererLänderimWeltsystemvon1820bis1986.Frankfurt,a.M.:
AntonHain,1990.

Winkler,Max.ForeignBonds:AnAutopsy.NewYork:RolandSwainCompany,1933.

21
22
Figure2.InteractionCoefficienttͲstatistics
70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
<Ͳ2 Ͳ2 Ͳ1.5 Ͳ1 Ͳ0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 >2

Notes:ThehistogramreportstherobusttͲstatisticsassociatedwiththe258interactiontermsthatresultfrom
estimatingequation(4)inthetextforeachofthe86bondsthatweretradedwhentheissuingcountrywasboth
onandoffthegoldstandard.


23
Table1.SelectedTestsoftheGoodͲHousekeepingHypothesis

  
Authors BaselineRegressionSpecification Controlsin ܺ௜௧ᇱ 
  
ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬௜௧ =ߙ௜ ൅ ߚ௜ ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬ௐ௧ ൅ ߜ‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ ൅ ܺ௜௧ᇱ ߛ ൅ ߝ௜௧  Laggedmoneygrowth
BordoͲRockoff
ߝ௜௧ ൌ ߩ௜ ߝ௜௧ିଵ ൅ ‫ݑ‬௜௧ LaggeddeficitͲGNPratio
  
Laggedinflation
LaggeddebtͲoutputlevel
ExportͲGDPratio
ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬௜௧ =ߙ௜ ൅ ߚ௜ ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬ௐ௧ ൅ߜଵ ‫ ܨܧܦ‬ൈ ‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ ൅ ߜଶ ܱܰ‫ ܨܧܦ‬ൈ ‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ ൅ܺ௜௧ᇱ ߛ ൅ ߝ௜௧
ObstfeldͲTaylor Realincomepercapita
ߝ௜௧ ൌ ߩ௜ ߝ௜௧ିଵ ൅ ‫ݑ‬௜௧ 
Termsoftrade
BritishEmpiredummy
Wardummies
  
InterestserviceͲrevenueratio
ReservesͲbanknotesratio
Exportspercapita
DeficitͲrevenueratio
ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬௜௧ =ߙ௜ +ߜ‫ܵܩ‬௜௧ ൅ ܺ௜௧ᇱ ߛ ൅ ߝ௜௧ 
FlandreauͲZumer ExchangeͲratevolatility
ߝ௜௧ ൌ ߩ௜ ߝ௜௧ିଵ ൅ ‫ݑ‬௜௧ 
Default
Memoryofdefault
Enfranchisedpopulation
Politicalcrisisdummies
Notes:ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬௜௧ ൌ ܻ݈݅݁݀௜௧ െ ܻ݈݅݁݀௎௄ǡ௧ .InBordoandRockoff,ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬ௐǡ௧ ൌ ܻ݈݅݁݀஺௏ீǡ௧ െ ܻ݈݅݁݀௎௄ǡ௧ ,whereܻ݈݅݁݀஺௏ீǡ௧ istheaverageofallcoupon
yieldsintheirsample.InObstfeldandTaylor,ܴܵܲ‫ܦܣܧ‬ௐǡ௧ ൌ ܻ݈݅݁݀ௐǡ௧ െ ܻ݈݅݁݀௎௄ǡ௧ ,whereܻ݈݅݁݀ௐǡ௧ istheGDPͲweightedaverageofallcouponyields
intheirsample.


 

24
Table2.ExcessReturnRegressions:OffandOnͲGoldPortfolios
 
 

  ValueͲWeighted    EquallyWeighted 
 OffGold OnGold OffെOn  OffGold OnGold OffെOn

MeanExcessReturn 4.24 2.71 1.53  4.33 2.90 1.43


ߙ Ͳ0.11 0.49 Ͳ0.59  Ͳ0.90 0.91* Ͳ1.80
(Ͳ0.08) (0.72) (Ͳ0.44) (Ͳ0.51) (1.92) (Ͳ1.09)
       
ߚ஼ைே  0.359*** 0.132*** 0.227**  0.321*** 0.153*** 0.168
(3.97) (2.78) (2.40) (2.60) (4.63) (1.45)
       
ߚெ௄்  0.407*** 0.305*** 0.101  0.730*** 0.245*** 0.485***
(5.00) (7.18) (1.19) (6.57) (8.26) (4.66)
       
ߚ஼ைோ௉  0.365*** 0.100* 0.265***  0.212 0.101*** 0.111
(3.73) (1.96) (2.58) (1.58) (2.83) (0.88)
       
ܴതଶ  0.208 0.126 0.062  0.179 0.180 0.087
 

Notes:Theregressionsareequations(2)and(3).Themeanexcessreturnandestimatedalphaareexpressedinannualized
percentagepoints.RobusttͲstatisticsareinparentheses.***(**)(*)indicatessignificanceatthe1%(5%)(10%)level.

25
Table3.Excess28ͲdayReturnRegressions:OffͲGoldPortfolio––OnGoldPortfolio

PanelA:ValueͲWeighted
 Full BordoͲRockoff BordoͲSchwartz ObstfeldͲTaylor FlandreauͲZumer

MeanExcessReturn 1.53 2.33 1.58 2.26 2.52


ߙ  Ͳ0.59 0.48 0.08 Ͳ0.37 0.70
(Ͳ0.44) (0.34) (0.07) (Ͳ0.23) (0.49)
 

ߚ஼ைே  0.227** 0.141 0.052 0.217** 0.314***


(2.40) (1.45) (0.60) (1.99) (3.18)
 

ߚெ௄்  0.101 Ͳ0.000 0.167** 0.134 Ͳ0.013


(1.19) (Ͳ0.01) (2.17) (1.37) (0.15)
 

ߚ஼ைோ௉  0.265*** 0.387*** 0.145 0.365*** 0.272**


(2.58) (3.69) (1.56) (3.09) (2.54)
 

ܴതଶ  0.062 0.045 0.027 0.069 0.047


SuccessRate 24.1% 68.9% 48.4% 39.1% 78.7%
 
 

PanelB:EquallyWeighted
 Full BordoͲRockoff BordoͲSchwartz ObstfeldͲTaylor FlandreauͲZumer
MeanExcessReturn 1.43 2.39 2.29 2.22 2.36
ߙ  Ͳ1.80 0.91 0.95 Ͳ0.39 0.39
(Ͳ1.09) (0.75) (0.82) (Ͳ0.28) (0.32)
 

ߚ஼ைே  0.168 0.082 0.011 0.094 0.187**


(1.45) (0.97) (0.14) (0.97) (2.19)
 

ߚெ௄்  0.485*** 0.076 0.167** 0.304*** 0.154**


(4.66) (1.01) (2.29) (3.50) (2.01)
 

ߚ஼ைோ௉  0.111 0.232** 0.130 0.231** 0.188**


(0.88) (2.54) (1.48) (2.21) (2.04)
 

ܴതଶ  0.087 0.030 0.028 0.078 0.053


SuccessRate 8.0% 78.1% 84.2% 36.2% 64.3%
 

Notes:Theregressionsareequations(2)and(3).Themeanexcessreturnandestimatedalphaareexpressedin
annualizedpercentagepoints.RobusttͲstatisticsareinparentheses.***(**)(*)indicatessignificanceatthe1%
(5%)(10%)level.

26
Table4.ExcessReturnRegressions:MacroeconomicRiskFactorsandIndependentCountries

       
 FullSample  Ind.Countries

 OffGold OnGold OffെOn  OffGold OnGold OffെOn

MeanExcessReturn 4.27 2.59 1.68  4.24 3.21 1.02

ߙ  0.03 0.24 Ͳ0.21  Ͳ0.11 0.81 Ͳ0.92


(0.02) (0.36) (Ͳ0.16) (Ͳ0.08) (1.01) (Ͳ0.65)
       
ߚ஼ைே  0.345*** 0.157*** 0.188**  0.359*** 0.117** 0.242**
(3.86) (3.40) (2.00) (3.97) (2.07) (2.46)
       
ߚெ௄்  0.366*** 0.185*** 0.181**  0.407*** 0.353*** 0.054
(4.48) (4.39) (2.10) (5.01) (6.98) (0.611)
       
ߚ஼ைோ௉  0.381*** 0.143*** 0.238**  0.365*** 0.097 0.268**
(3.97) (2.89) (Ͳ2.35) (3.73) (1.59) (2.52)
       
ߚ஽ாிିீ஽௉  Ͳ0.061 0.089*** Ͳ0.150**   

(Ͳ1.03) (2.94) (Ͳ2.41)
       
ߚூேி  Ͳ0.124*** Ͳ0.053** Ͳ0.071   

(Ͳ2.88) (Ͳ2.38) (Ͳ1.57)
       
ߚா௑௉ିீ஽௉  Ͳ0.172*** Ͳ0.189*** 0.017   

(Ͳ3.75) (Ͳ8.01) (0.36)
       
ܴത ଶ  0.237 0.252 0.091  0.208 0.112 0.052
Notes:Theregressionsareequations(2)and(3).TheportfoliosarevalueͲweighted.Themeanexcessreturnand
estimatedalphaareexpressedinannualizedpercentagepoints.The““Ind.Countries””sampleincludesall
independentcountriesinoursampleandexcludestheBritishcolonies.““DefͲGDP””,““Inf””,and““ExpͲGDP””referto
thecoefficientsassociatedwiththefactorͲmimickingportfoliosdescribedinthetext.RobusttͲstatisticsarein
parentheses.***(**)(*)indicatessignificanceatthe1%(5%)(10%)level.

27
Appendix1:SampleofCountries
Thedatasetincludes213sovereignbondsissuedby37nonͲcolonialcountriesand110colonial
bondsissuedby12Britishcoloniesandpossessions.Thepricesaresampledevery28daysfrom
theofficialquotationlistpublishedintheMoneyMarketReviewandtheEconomistfrom1866
until1907,whenthepublisherceasedprovidingsuchdetailedpricequotations.Weusethe
price,dividend,andcoupondatatocomputeatimeseriesofrealizedholdingͲperiodreturns
correctedfordividends,stocksplits,andsovereigndefaults.Todatesovereigndefaults,werely
ontheannualreportsissuedbytheCouncilofForeignBondholders,Winkler(1933),andSuter
(1990).Intheregressions,thetimeseriesspantheperiodfromJanuary1870untilDecember
1907duetodataconstraints.

SovereignBondData
Thecountriesincludedinourdatasetare:Argentina;Australia;AustriaͲHungary;Belgium;
Brazil;BritishGuiana;Bulgaria;Canada;Ceylon;Chile;China;Colombia;CostaRica;Denmark;
Ecuador;Egypt;France;Germany;Greece;Guatemala;Hawaii;Honduras;HongKong;Italy;
Jamaica;Japan;Liberia;Mauritius;Mexico;Netherlands;NewZealand;Nicaragua;Norway;
OrangeFreeState;Paraguay;Peru;Portugal;Russia;SaintLucia;SantoDomingo;SouthAfrica;
Spain;StraitsSettlements;Sweden;Trinidad;Turkey;UnitedStates;Uruguay;andVenezuela.

TheBritishcoloniesandpossessionsareasubsetofthecountriesinthefullsample.Theyare:
Australia;BritishGuiana;Canada;Ceylon;HongKong;Jamaica;Mauritius;NewZealand;Saint
Lucia;SouthAfrica;StraitsSettlements;andTrinidad.

Subsamples
Weformedsubsamplesofcountriesbaseduponpreviousworkonthegoldstandard.Weare
abletomimiccloselyeachofthesamplesofcountrieslistedbelow.

BordoandRockoff(1996):Argentina;Australia;Brazil;Canada;Chile;Italy;Portugal;Spain;and
UnitedStates.

28

BordoandSchwartz(1999):Argentina;Australia;Belgium;Brazil;Canada;Chile;Denmark;
Finland;Greece;Italy;Japan;Netherlands;Norway;Portugal;Sweden;andSwitzerland.The
fourcorecountriesareFrance,Germany,theUK,andtheUnitedStates.WeexcludeFinland
andSwitzerlandduetolackofdata.

ObstfeldandTaylor(2003):Argentina;Australia;AustriaͲHungary;Brazil;Canada;Chile;Egypt;
Greece;India;Italy;Japan;Mexico;NewZealand;Norway;Portugal;SouthAfrica;Spain;
Sweden;Turkey;theUnitedStates;andUruguay.

FlandreauandZumer(2004):Argentina;AustriaͲHungary;Belgium;Brazil;Denmark;France;
Germany;Greece;Italy;Netherlands;Norway;Portugal;Spain;Sweden;Switzerland;and
Russia.WeexcludeSwitzerlandduetolackofdata.

WeadoptthedefinitionofcheaterfromBordoandSchwartz’’sTable1(BordoandSchwartz
1999).Wecodeacountryasacheaterifitsuspendedgoldconvertibilitybecauseofwar,lax
fiscalpolicy,afinancialcrisis,failedconvertibility,orsomecombinationofthefour.The
countriesthatfallintothiscategoryareArgentina,Brazil,Chile,Greece,Italy,andPortugal.
 

29
Appendix2:GoldͲstandardadherence
Argentina:January3,1867ͲMay1876:LeavinggoldinMay1876didnotresultinachangein
parity.July1883ͲDecember1884:LeavinggoldinDecember1884didnotresultinachangeof
parity.October31,1899:Lawestablishingexternalconvertibility.Source:dellaPaoleraand
Taylor(2001),pp.25,41,47.

Australia:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Source:Meissner
(2005).

AustriaͲHungary:August2,1892.Source:Helfferich(1927),pp.200.

Belgium:November5,1878.Source:Helfferich(1927),pp.180.

Brazil:October1888ͲOctober1890.LeavinggoldinOctober1890didnotresultinachangeof
parity.December31,1906:ConversionOfficeopened.Sources:MartinͲAcena(2000),pp155;
andSubercaseaux(1931).

BritishGuiana:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Source:
Officer(2001).

Bulgaria:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:
Meissner(2005).

Canada:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Newfoundlanddid
notadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogolduntil1895,accordingtoOfficer(2001).
WedatethebondsfromNewfoundlandfromJanuary1,1895.Sources:Meissner(2005).

Ceylon:1898.WedateCeylonasadheringtothegoldstandardfromJanuary1,1898.Source:
Officer(2001).

Chile:LawpassedFebruary11,1895providingforconversionfromJune1,1895.Suspended
convertibilityJuly31,1898.Thiseventresultedinachangeofparity.Source:Kemmerer(1926).

China:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:
Bloomfield(1959).

Colombia:From1903,Colombiahasfixedgoldparities,butitdidnotadoptacompletegold
standarduntil1923,whenthefirstKemmererMissionintervened.WecodeColombiaasnot

30
adoptingthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:MartinͲAcena(2000),
pp.237.

CostaRica:LawpassedinOctober1896,butcurrencywasnotconvertibleintogolduntilJuly
15,1900.WedateitfromNovember1896.Source:Young(1925),pp.193Ͳ96.

Denmark:AgreementreachedDecember18,1872.FormedmonetaryunionwithSwedenin
May1873.WedateitfromJune1873.Sources:Helfferich(1927),pp.175;andJonung(1984),
pp.367.

Ecuador:1900.WedateEcuadorasadheringtothegoldstandardfromJanuary1,1900.
Source:Meissner(2005).

Egypt:1885.WedateEgyptasadheringtothegoldstandardfromJanuary1,1885.Source:
Officer(2001).

France:November5,1878.Source:Helfferich(1927),pp.180.

Germany:December4,1871.Source:Helfferich(1927),pp.156Ͳ7.

Greece:January1885ͲSeptember1885.Thiseventdidnotresultinachangeofparity.Greece
didnotjointhegoldstandardagainuntilMarch1910.Sources:BordoandSchwartz(1999),pp.
251;andLazaretou(2005).

Guatemala:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:
BulmerͲThomas(2003),pp112.

Hawaii:AdoptedtheGoldLawof1884,whichmadethegoldcoinsoftheUnitedStateslegal
tender.WedateHawaiiasadheringtothegoldstandardfromJanuary1,1884.Source:Tate
(1965),pp.69.

Honduras:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:
BulmerͲThomas(2003),pp112.

HongKong:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:Tom
(1989).


31
Italy:LawestablishingconvertibilityApril12,1884passedMarch1,1883.Affidavitintroduced
onsecondsemestercouponpaymentsinJuly1893.RequiredItalianstoswearrenditacoupon
paymentsreceivedabroaddidnotbelongtoItaliancitizens.Introducedincentivesforlenders
toredeeminMilan.Thiseventresultedinachangeinparity.Sources:Helfferich(1927),pp.
175;andFratianniandSpinelli(1984),pp.415.

Jamaica:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Source:Officer
(2001).

Japan:LawpassedMarch29,1897providingforconversionbetweenOctober1,1897ͲJuly31,
1898.Sources:Helfferich(1927),pp.201;andLaughlin(1900).

Liberia:PeggedtoUSdollarattheexchangerateL$1=US$1.WecodeitthesameastheUS.
Source:http://users.erols.com/kurrency/africa.htm

Mauritius:1898.WedateMauritiusasadheringtothegoldstandardfromJanuary1,1898.
Source:Officer(2001).

Mexico:LawpassedDecember9,1904.DecreeenforcedMarch25,1905.Source:Helfferich
(1927),pp.204.

Netherlands:June6,1875.Source:Helfferich(1927),pp.176.

NewZealand:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Source:Officer
(2001).

Nicaragua:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Sources:
BulmerͲThomas(2003),pp115;andYoung(1925),pp.119Ͳ30;AppendixE.

Norway:AgreementreachedDecember18,1872.Norwayformedamonetaryunionwith
DenmarkandSwedeninOctober1875.Sources:Helfferich(1927),pp.175;andJonung(1984),
pp.367.

OrangeFreeState:1870ͲDecember14,1899.December15,1899ͲMarch14,1900:Gold
standardsuspended.March15,1900Ͳ1910:GoldstandardreͲestablished.Source:
http://users.erols.com/kurrency/africa.htm


32
Paraguay:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:
BulmerͲThomas(2003),pp114.

Peru:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:Meissner
(2005).

Portugal:1854ͲMay1891.Thiseventresultedinachangeinparity.Source:Reis(2000),pp94.

Russia:February1897.Source:Anonymous(1897).

St.Lucia:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Source:Officer
(2001).

SantoDomingo:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.
Sources:Laughlin(1894);andMeissner(2005).

SouthAfrica:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Source:Officer
(2001).

Spain:Suspendedsummer1883becauseofdeclineinforeigninvestmentafterJanuary1882
stockmarketcrash.Theprecisedateisvague,andwedateitfromtheendofJune1883.
Source:MartinͲAcena(2000),pp128.

StraitsSettlements:1903.WedatetheStraitsSettlementsasadheringtothegoldstandard
fromJanuary1,1903.Source:Meissner(2005).

Sweden:AgreementreachedDecember18,1872.FormedmonetaryunionwithDenmarkin
May1873.Sources:Helfferich(1927),pp.175;andJonung(1984),pp.367.

Trinidad:Adoptedthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1870.Source:Officer
(2001).

Turkey:1881.WedateTurkeyasadheringtothegoldstandardfromJanuary1,1881Sources:
Pamuk(2000),pp.218.

UnitedStates:January1,1879.Source:Officer(2001).


33
Uruguay:1885.WedateUruguayasadheringtothegoldstandardfromJanuary1,1885.
Source:Meissner(2005).

Venezuela:Didnotadoptthefreeconvertibilityofcurrencyintogoldbefore1914.Source:
Meissner(2005).
 

34
AppendixReferences
Anonymous.““SpecieResumptioninRussia.””JournalofPoliticalEconomy5,no.2(1897):241Ͳ
244.

Bloomfield,Arthur.MonetaryPolicyUndertheGoldStandard.NewYork:FederalReserveBank
ofNewYork,1959.

Bordo,MichaelD.,andAnnaJ.Schwartz.““TheOperationoftheSpecieStandard:Evidencefor
CoreandPeripheralCountries:1880Ͳ1990.””InTheGoldStandardandRelatedRegimes:
CollectedEssays,editedbyMichaelD.Bordo,238Ͳ317.NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress,
1999.

BulmerͲThomas,Victor.TheEconomicHistoryofLatinAmericasinceIndependence.NewYork:
CambridgeUniversityPress,2003.

DellaPaolera,Gerardo,andAlanTaylor.StrainingattheAnchor:TheArgentineCurrencyBoard
andtheSearchforMacroeconomicStability:1880Ͳ1935.Chicago:UniversityofChicagoPress,
2001.

Fratianni,Michele,andFrancoSpinelli.““ItalyintheGoldStandardPeriod,1861Ͳ1914.””InA
RetrospectiveontheClassicalGoldStandard:1821Ͳ1931,editedbyMichaelD.BordoandAnna
J.Schwartz,405Ͳ454.Chicago:UniversityofChicagoPress,1984.

Helfferich,Karl.Money,2vols.TranslatedbyLouisInfield.NewYork:AdelphiCompany
Publishers,1927.

Jonung,Lars.““SwedishExperienceundertheClassicalGoldStandard:1873Ͳ1914.””InA
RetrospectiveontheClassicalGoldStandard:1821Ͳ1931,editedbyMichaelD.BordoandAnna
J.Schwartz,361Ͳ399.Chicago:UniversityofChicagoPress,1984.

Kemmerer,EdwinWalter.““ChileReturnstoGoldStandard.””JournalofPoliticalEconomy34,no.
3(1926):265Ͳ273.

Laughlin,J.Laurence.““GoldandSilverinSantoDomingo.””JournalofPoliticalEconomy2,no.4
(1894):536Ͳ560.

__________““ReportontheAdoptionoftheGoldStandardinJapan.””JournalofPolitical
Economy8,no.3(1900):424Ͳ427.

35

Lazaretou,Sophia.““TheDrachma,ForeignCreditors,andtheInternationalMonetarySystem:
TalesofaCurrencyduringthe19thand20thCenturies.””ExplorationsinEconomicHistory42,no.
2(2005):202Ͳ236.

MartinͲAcena,Pablo.““TheSpanishMonetaryExperience:1848Ͳ1914.””InMonetaryStandards
inthePeriphery,editedbyPabloMartinAcenaandJaimeReis,112Ͳ151.NewYork:St.Martin’’s
Press,2000.

Meissner,Chris.““ANewWorldOrder:ExplainingtheInternationalDiffusionoftheGold
Standard,1870Ͳ1913.””JournalofInternationalEconomics66,no.2(2005):385Ͳ406.

Officer,Lawrence.““GoldStandard.””EH.NetEncyclopedia,editedbyRobertWhaples.October1,
2001.URLhttp://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/officer.gold.standard

Pamuk,Sevket.AMonetaryHistoryoftheOttomanEmpire.NewYork:CambridgeUniversity
Press,2000.

Reis,Jamie.““TheGoldStandardinPortugal:1854Ͳ1891.””InMonetaryStandardsinthe
Periphery,editedbyPabloMartinͲAcenaandJaimeReis,69Ͳ111.NewYork:St.Martin’’sPress,
2000.

Subercaseaux,Guillermo.““TheModernGoldStandardwithIllustrationsfromSouthAmerica.””
AmericanEconomicReview21,no.2(1931):249Ͳ259.

Suter,Christian.SchuldenzykleninderdrittenWelt:Kreditaufnahme,Zahlungskrisenund
SchuldenregelungenperiphererLänderimWeltsystemvon1820bis1986.Frankfurt,a.M.:
AntonHain,1990.

Tate,Merze.TheUnitedStatesandtheHawaiianKingdom.NewHavenandLondon:Yale
UniversityPress,1965.

Tom,C.F.Joseph.MonetaryProblemsofanEntrepot:TheHongKongExperience.NewYork:
PeterLangPublishing,1989.

Winkler,Max.ForeignBonds:AnAutopsy.NewYork:RolandSwainCompany,1933.

36

Young,JohnParke.CentralAmericanCurrencyandFinance.Princeton:PrincetonUniversity
Press,1925.


37
Working Paper Series
A series of research studies on regional economic issues relating to the Seventh Federal
Reserve District, and on financial and economic topics.

Risk Taking and the Quality of Informal Insurance: Gambling and Remittances in Thailand WP-07-01
Douglas L. Miller and Anna L. Paulson

Fast Micro and Slow Macro: Can Aggregation Explain the Persistence of Inflation? WP-07-02
Filippo Altissimo, Benoît Mojon, and Paolo Zaffaroni

Assessing a Decade of Interstate Bank Branching WP-07-03


Christian Johnson and Tara Rice

Debit Card and Cash Usage: A Cross-Country Analysis WP-07-04


Gene Amromin and Sujit Chakravorti

The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions Over the Lifecycle WP-07-05


Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction WP-07-06


Gadi Barlevy and Pietro Veronesi

Monetary Policy, Output Composition and the Great Moderation WP-07-07


Benoît Mojon

Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth WP-07-08


Marco Cagetti and Mariacristina De Nardi

Conflict of Interest and Certification in the U.S. IPO Market WP-07-09


Luca Benzoni and Carola Schenone

The Reaction of Consumer Spending and Debt to Tax Rebates –


Evidence from Consumer Credit Data WP-07-10
Sumit Agarwal, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated WP-07-11
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

Nonparametric Analysis of Intergenerational Income Mobility WP-07-12


with Application to the United States
Debopam Bhattacharya and Bhashkar Mazumder

How the Credit Channel Works: Differentiating the Bank Lending Channel WP-07-13
and the Balance Sheet Channel
Lamont K. Black and Richard J. Rosen

Labor Market Transitions and Self-Employment WP-07-14


Ellen R. Rissman

First-Time Home Buyers and Residential Investment Volatility WP-07-15


Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

1
Working Paper Series (continued)
Establishments Dynamics and Matching Frictions in Classical Competitive Equilibrium WP-07-16
Marcelo Veracierto

Technology’s Edge: The Educational Benefits of Computer-Aided Instruction WP-07-17


Lisa Barrow, Lisa Markman, and Cecilia Elena Rouse

The Widow’s Offering: Inheritance, Family Structure, and the Charitable Gifts of Women WP-07-18
Leslie McGranahan

Incomplete Information and the Timing to Adjust Labor: Evidence from the
Lead-Lag Relationship between Temporary Help Employment and Permanent Employment WP-07-19
Sainan Jin, Yukako Ono, and Qinghua Zhang

A Conversation with 590 Nascent Entrepreneurs WP-07-20


Jeffrey R. Campbell and Mariacristina De Nardi

Cyclical Dumping and US Antidumping Protection: 1980-2001 WP-07-21


Meredith A. Crowley

Health Capital and the Prenatal Environment:


The Effect of Maternal Fasting During Pregnancy WP-07-22
Douglas Almond and Bhashkar Mazumder

The Spending and Debt Response to Minimum Wage Hikes WP-07-23


Daniel Aaronson, Sumit Agarwal, and Eric French

The Impact of Mexican Immigrants on U.S. Wage Structure WP-07-24


Maude Toussaint-Comeau

A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles WP-08-01


Gadi Barlevy

Displacement, Asymmetric Information and Heterogeneous Human Capital WP-08-02


Luojia Hu and Christopher Taber

BankCaR (Bank Capital-at-Risk): A credit risk model for US commercial bank charge-offs WP-08-03
Jon Frye and Eduard Pelz

Bank Lending, Financing Constraints and SME Investment WP-08-04


Santiago Carbó-Valverde, Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández, and Gregory F. Udell

Global Inflation WP-08-05


Matteo Ciccarelli and Benoît Mojon

Scale and the Origins of Structural Change WP-08-06


Francisco J. Buera and Joseph P. Kaboski

Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and Large Devaluations WP-08-07


George Alessandria, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan
2
Working Paper Series (continued)
School Vouchers and Student Achievement: Recent Evidence, Remaining Questions WP-08-08
Cecilia Elena Rouse and Lisa Barrow

Does It Pay to Read Your Junk Mail? Evidence of the Effect of Advertising on
Home Equity Credit Choices WP-08-09
Sumit Agarwal and Brent W. Ambrose

The Choice between Arm’s-Length and Relationship Debt: Evidence from eLoans WP-08-10
Sumit Agarwal and Robert Hauswald

Consumer Choice and Merchant Acceptance of Payment Media WP-08-11


Wilko Bolt and Sujit Chakravorti

Investment Shocks and Business Cycles WP-08-12


Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti

New Vehicle Characteristics and the Cost of the


Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standard WP-08-13
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

Realized Volatility WP-08-14


Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

Revenue Bubbles and Structural Deficits: What’s a state to do? WP-08-15


Richard Mattoon and Leslie McGranahan

The role of lenders in the home price boom WP-08-16


Richard J. Rosen

Bank Crises and Investor Confidence WP-08-17


Una Okonkwo Osili and Anna Paulson

Life Expectancy and Old Age Savings WP-08-18


Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

Remittance Behavior among New U.S. Immigrants WP-08-19


Katherine Meckel

Birth Cohort and the Black-White Achievement Gap:


The Roles of Access and Health Soon After Birth WP-08-20
Kenneth Y. Chay, Jonathan Guryan, and Bhashkar Mazumder

Public Investment and Budget Rules for State vs. Local Governments WP-08-21
Marco Bassetto

Why Has Home Ownership Fallen Among the Young? WP-09-01


Jonas D.M. Fisher and Martin Gervais

Why do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses WP-09-02


Mariacristina De Nardi, Eric French, and John Bailey Jones

3
Working Paper Series (continued)
Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks WP-09-03
Jonas D.M. Fisher and Ryan Peters

Stochastic Volatility WP-09-04


Torben G. Andersen and Luca Benzoni

The Effect of Disability Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply WP-09-05


Eric French and Jae Song

CEO Overconfidence and Dividend Policy WP-09-06


Sanjay Deshmukh, Anand M. Goel, and Keith M. Howe

Do Financial Counseling Mandates Improve Mortgage Choice and Performance? WP-09-07


Evidence from a Legislative Experiment
Sumit Agarwal,Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet,
and Douglas D. Evanoff

Perverse Incentives at the Banks? Evidence from a Natural Experiment WP-09-08


Sumit Agarwal and Faye H. Wang

Pay for Percentile WP-09-09


Gadi Barlevy and Derek Neal

The Life and Times of Nicolas Dutot WP-09-10


François R. Velde

Regulating Two-Sided Markets: An Empirical Investigation WP-09-11


Santiago Carbó Valverde, Sujit Chakravorti, and Francisco Rodriguez Fernandez

The Case of the Undying Debt WP-09-12


François R. Velde

Paying for Performance: The Education Impacts of a Community College Scholarship


Program for Low-income Adults WP-09-13
Lisa Barrow, Lashawn Richburg-Hayes, Cecilia Elena Rouse, and Thomas Brock

Establishments Dynamics, Vacancies and Unemployment: A Neoclassical Synthesis WP-09-14


Marcelo Veracierto

The Price of Gasoline and the Demand for Fuel Economy:


Evidence from Monthly New Vehicles Sales Data WP-09-15
Thomas Klier and Joshua Linn

Estimation of a Transformation Model with Truncation,


Interval Observation and Time-Varying Covariates WP-09-16
Bo E. Honoré and Luojia Hu

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements: Evidence from Antidumping Policy WP-09-17


Chad P. Bown and Meredith A. Crowley

Too much right can make a wrong: Setting the stage for the financial crisis WP-09-18
Richard J. Rosen
4
Working Paper Series (continued)
Can Structural Small Open Economy Models Account
for the Influence of Foreign Disturbances? WP-09-19
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

Liquidity Constraints of the Middle Class WP-09-20


Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz

Monetary Policy and Uncertainty in an Empirical Small Open Economy Model WP-09-21
Alejandro Justiniano and Bruce Preston

Firm boundaries and buyer-supplier match in market transaction:


IT system procurement of U.S. credit unions WP-09-22
Yukako Ono and Junichi Suzuki

Health and the Savings of Insured Versus Uninsured, Working-Age Households in the U.S. WP-09-23
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Jonathan Hartley

The Economics of “Radiator Springs:” Industry Dynamics, Sunk Costs, and


Spatial Demand Shifts WP-09-24
Jeffrey R. Campbell and Thomas N. Hubbard

On the Relationship between Mobility, Population Growth, and


Capital Spending in the United States WP-09-25
Marco Bassetto and Leslie McGranahan

The Impact of Rosenwald Schools on Black Achievement WP-09-26


Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar Mazumder

Comment on “Letting Different Views about Business Cycles Compete” WP-10-01


Jonas D.M. Fisher

Macroeconomic Implications of Agglomeration WP-10-02


Morris A. Davis, Jonas D.M. Fisher and Toni M. Whited

Accounting for non-annuitization WP-10-03


Svetlana Pashchenko

Robustness and Macroeconomic Policy WP-10-04


Gadi Barlevy

Benefits of Relationship Banking: Evidence from Consumer Credit Markets WP-10-05


Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas S. Souleles

The Effect of Sales Tax Holidays on Household Consumption Patterns WP-10-06


Nathan Marwell and Leslie McGranahan

Gathering Insights on the Forest from the Trees: A New Metric for Financial Conditions WP-10-07
Scott Brave and R. Andrew Butters

Identification of Models of the Labor Market WP-10-08


Eric French and Christopher Taber

5
Working Paper Series (continued)
Public Pensions and Labor Supply Over the Life Cycle WP-10-09
Eric French and John Jones

Explaining Asset Pricing Puzzles Associated with the 1987 Market Crash WP-10-10
Luca Benzoni, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, and Robert S. Goldstein

Does SexǦSelective Abortion Improve Girls’ WellǦBeing? Evidence from India WP-10-11
Luojia Hu and Analía Schlosser

Mortgage Choices and Housing Speculation WP-10-12


Gadi Barlevy and Jonas D.M. Fisher

Did Adhering to the Gold Standard Reduce the Cost of Capital? WP-10-13
Ron Alquist and Benjamin Chabot

También podría gustarte