Está en la página 1de 11

Global Policy Volume 3 . Issue 3 .

September 2012
281

Economic Nationalism: Theory,


History and Prospects
Sam Pryke

Research Article
Wolverhampton University

Abstract
This article makes both a theoretical and empirical contribution to understanding economic nationalism. It does this
first through providing an appropriate definition of the term. Taking issue with the generalised remit of economic
nationalism in recent writings, it suggests that it consists of practices to create, bolster and protect national
economies in the context of world markets. Taking this definition, the subsequent history section identifies economic
nationalism’s rise in the late 19th century, the impetus of crisis after 1929 and its institutionalisation after 1945.
Simultaneously, the accelerating growth of world markets through greater exports undermined the reality of national
economies. This takes us to the period after the financial crash of 2008. In its aftermath, commentators warned of a
resurgence of economic nationalism, that is, protectionism. Some states did increase tariff levels but this has not led
to a generalised increase in barriers to trade in the pursuit of national economies for interrelated reasons: (1) the
integration and therefore interdependency of economies; (2) the complexity of the global economy, making it all but
impossible to separate by nationality; (3) the greater extensity of world markets compared to the mid-20th century; (4)
the redundancy of the various models of economic nationalism.

Policy Implications
• Economic nationalism should be understood as a set of practices to create, bolster and protect national economies
in the context of world markets. The rise and institutionalisation of economic nationalism in the 20th century was
a product of economic crisis, nationalist movements and enlarged states.
• There has been no ‘return of economic nationalism’ as in a generalised rise in protective barriers to trade since the
financial crash of 2011. Unlike the 1930s, sovereign debt has not motivated states to withdraw from global markets.
• The integration, complexity and extensity of the world’s economy mean that a reversal of trade as great as during the
interwar period would entail an economic Armageddon. Whatever future ructions the world’s economy experiences
due, above all, to chronic levels of sovereign debt, policy makers should be mindful of this reality.
• Simultaneously, they should be aware that ongoing instability may entail greater economic nationalism. The key les-
son from the period after the Second World War is relevant now at a more overtly global level: the importance of plan-
ning, regulation and respect for models of economic diversity to further global trade.

Four years since the financial crash of the autumn of pronounced from the autumn of 2008 to the winter of
2008, the outlook for the world economy is uncertain. 2009. This is hardly surprising if economic nationalism is
What does seem clear is that a much mooted return of taken to be a knee-jerk political response to crisis given
economic nationalism, construed as a generalised rise in the scale of the financial meltdown.
protectionism, has not occurred. Politicians and com- Take three examples of this discourse. In Britain Vince
mentators have repeatedly warned that financial crisis Cable, the then Liberal Democrat Finance spokesman,
and recession might induce a shift away by governments now the Business Secretary in the Conservative-led coali-
from the globalisation of our times to the economic tion government, cautioned readers of New Statesman in
nationalism of the 1930s. Now, as Harold James (2001, p. October 2008 that greater state involvement in capital-
204) says, ‘At regular intervals since the publication of ism through bank bailouts should not be equated with a
David Ricardo’s Principles of Political Economy in 1817, return to Keynes, let alone Marx, but nationalism (Cable,
analysts have been predicting the imminent death of 2008): ‘The ingredients are in place, in the UK and else-
free-trade’. This aside, the forebodings were especially where, for a return to atavistic ‘‘politics of the soil’’: the

Global Policy (2012) 3:3 doi: 10.1111/j.1758-5899.2011.00146.x ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Sam Pryke
282

politics of identity, and old-fashioned economic national- it considers whether the term has any relevance in the
ism’. He traced such reactions back to 1720 when the period after the financial crash of 2008.
political fallout from the South Sea Bubble saw a ban on
the importation of Indian textiles. During early 2009, The
Economic nationalism: definition and remit
Economist repeatedly warned of the ‘rising spectre’ of
economic nationalism. On February 5th (The Economist, Writing on economic nationalism in recent years has
2009a) it claimed that although ‘global supply chains are come from various sources with, as is often the case,
more complex and harder to pick apart than those days little cross-referencing between the various authors. On
(the early 1930s)’, when ‘nationalism is on the march, the one hand, there are polemical accounts, similar to
even commercial logic gets trampled underfoot’. The The Economist, that equate it with the historic obsta-
magazine stressed that ‘American leadership [to avert a cles states erected before and after the first era of free
trade war] is the only chance’. Two weeks later a longer trade in the mid-19th century. For instance, Martin
and more considered piece (The Economist, 2009b), not- Wolf in Why Globalization Works (2004) argues that the
withstanding a title of ‘Turning their Backs on the World’, return to premodern mercantilism through militarism,
concluded: ‘Despite the downturn, the nations of the imperialism and economic nationalism in the late 19th
world have not shunned globalisation. It has been pro- century stifled free trade, curtailed democracy and pre-
tected by the belief of firms in the efficiency of global cipitated war: ‘From the point of view of promoting
supply chains’. The contradictory messages of The Econo- prosperity these shifts were an error’ (Wolf, 2004,
mist perhaps indicate a wider confusion in the ideologi- p. 37).
cal defence of capitalism in this period: a faith in the Within the study of nationalism there has been rela-
essential good of free trade, beside the self-evident fail- tively little direct coverage of economic matters in the
ure of financial markets to regulate themselves. Hence explosion of writings over the last 20 years. Economic
the fallback position that even if boom and bust had matters are, however, central to the key debate on the
not disappeared as complacently assumed, the alterna- periodisation of nationalism. The modernist thesis of Eric
tive to free trade that arose last time there was a crisis Hobsbawm (1992) is that nationalism was integral to an
of such magnitude presented the ultimate danger. A age when states had the ability to establish national
third and predictable example is in relation to fears of economies. Now that this age has been superseded by a
the possible collapse of the Euro. Robert Zoellick, the global one in which capital is mobile, the raison d’être of
outgoing President of the World Bank, warned in June nationalism has been undermined and will therefore
2012 (The Guardian, 2012) that the collapse of the cur- decline. The phenomenon is, as he puts it (Hobsbawm,
rency could trigger a ‘financial meltdown’ that would 1992, p. 192), ‘past its peak’.
have ‘desperate consequences’ – including the demand The ethnosymbolist understanding of nationalism of
for economic nationalism. ‘This is not just an economic Anthony D. Smith should not be considered the polar
crisis but a political threat as well’, he said. ‘We must opposite of the modernist account. Some of Smith’s
make sure we keep markets open and beware against numerous publications review what aspects of the mod-
creeping protectionism. We are starting to see some ernist case are valid. In his 1998 synthesis of his critique
increase in the use of trade restrictions’.1 (Smith, 1998, p. 49), he notes that economic nationalism
Irrespective of the exaggerated rhetoric, there was should be seen as a political reaction to the uneven and
some retreat from economic liberalisation after October combined development of capitalism. He cites Japan
2008 as a number of states raised tariffs, but this was after the Meiji Restoration of 1868 as a reactive instance
not pronounced and systematic. Specifically, there has that prized industrialisation to compete with external
been no equivalent of the Smoot-Hawley Congressional competitors. The language of national self-depiction in
Bill of June 1930 that raised duties on over 20,000 US this quest was set by a pre-existing Japanese identity.
imports to record levels, provoking retaliatory measures The role of pre-existing national identity is central to
across the world. The international agreements on tariffs Smith’s (1995) earlier consideration of nationalism and
of the World Trade Organization (WTO) have held and, globalisation. Here Smith rejected the view that national-
while the efforts of G20 leaders to coordinate a global ism arises within modernity to play an ideological role in
response to the crisis have been limited, states have not the state organisation of national economies, only to be
pulled away from each other as in the 1930s. ushered reluctantly from the historical stage when it
The fact that economic nationalism as defined in these becomes superfluous. Rather, as nations and nationalism
terms has not happened presents a timely opportunity are intrinsic to memory and tradition within humanity,
to reconsider the subject. This is the objective of this they are far more durable phenomena. If anything the
article. It considers first what definition and remit should homogenisation of globalisation will trigger archaic com-
be given to economic nationalism. Second, it looks at pensation as peoples resist the smothering of their dis-
the origination and rise of economic nationalism. Third, tinctive identities.

ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:3
Economic Nationalism
283

A major reconsideration of economic nationalism has commercial self-interest of Hindu business migrants in
taken place over the last 13 years from writers who are Europe and North America contributed to the liberalising
professional international political economists, an aca- direction of the governments of the Bharatiya Janata
demic offshoot of international relations. Their theoreti- party (BJP) in India in the 1990s – ‘long-distance free
cal endeavour has been to re-evaluate the realist notion market nationalism’ to combine the terms of Benedict
that economic nationalism is a protectionist policy Anderson (1998) and Shulman.
instrument of states akin to mercantilism – neomercantil- These revisions of economic nationalism inform subse-
ism. Although his direct contribution is slight, Robert Gil- quent writings in the middle of the last decade. Takeshi
pin is usually identified by his critics as providing the Nakano (2004) attempted to locate the role of nationalist
standard formulation of this approach. He describes (Gil- motivation of economic affairs in a conceptualisation of
pin, 1987, p. 31) economic nationalism as a ‘central idea a national economic state. The following year, Eric Helle-
that economic activities are and should be subordinate iner and Andreas Pickel (2005) brought together a num-
to the goal of state building and the interests of the ber of scholars who, broadly, take the view that
state’. It acts therefore as a tool as they ‘struggle for economic nationalism is a changing phenomenon. In
supreme power in the anarchic world of international introduction they reject the view that it is old, truculent
affairs’ (Gilpin, 2001, p. 14). This approach still has uncrit- and indicative of developing countries. They suggest
ical proponents. O’Brien and Williams (2007, p. 17) write that the general negative treatment of the term
in a core undergraduate text: ‘If realism is the perspec- obscures nationalism’s importance in economic affairs,
tive in international politics, economic nationalism is the and they offer a definition sufficiently broad to capture
equivalent in political economy’. its various motivations, rather than tying it to normative
The most substantial contribution to understanding concerns: ‘Nationalism should be understood fundamen-
economic nationalism within international relations was tally as a generic discursive structure rather than any
produced by James Mayall in 1990 (Mayall, 1990). May- particular substantive doctrine … Nationalism is a com-
all’s commitment to realism in explaining the behaviour bination of discourse, action and structure’ (Helleiner
of states is less explicit than Gilpin’s. Instead, he posits a and Pickel, 2005, pp. 7–8). As nations continue to repro-
tension between nationalism and economic liberalism, duce themselves rather than fade away, so economic
one that largely shaped the emergence of the interna- nationalism will persist. Addressing the question of
tional system of states and markets. The upshot is an whether globalisation will make economic nationalism
inherent fragility in the rules established to allow market redundant directly, Helleiner and Pickel (2005, p. 228)
interaction. Although governments may progressively state: ‘From our perspective so long as nationalism and
withdraw from involvement in trade and so on, national national identities endure, so too will various forms of
economic interests limit the depoliticisation of markets. economic nationalism’.
Such understandings of economic nationalism were One of the contributors to their book, Rawi Abdelal,
first scrutinised in 1998 by George T. Crane in an article had earlier produced the most substantial contribution
indicatively entitled ‘Economic Nationalism: Bringing the to the new approach to economic nationalism. In com-
Nation Back In’ (Crane, 1998). In it, Crane stresses the mon with other recent writings, the starting point of his
importance of the national in economic nationalism, National Purpose in the World Economy (Abdelal, 2001) is
rather than seeing it as a policy instrument of the state. the shortcomings of the realist understanding of eco-
Crucial to the economic orientation of a state is the self- nomic nationalism outlined above. Abdelal (2001, p. 34)
image of a nation at a particular conjuncture. For claims that seeing the state like Gilpin as an ‘autono-
instance, German manufacturers in the 19th century sup- mous actor pursuing statist economic nationalist policies’
ported Friedrich List’s advocacy of protective tariffs on cannot explain the aftermath of the disintegration of the
imports to boost infant industries in competition with Soviet trading block in 1991 following the collapse of
British firms, because they perceived their nation as a the USSR. Specifically, realism cannot make sense of the
collection of backward states. varied orientations of the independent successor states
Two years later Stephen Shulman gave this reconfigu- towards and away from economic integration with Rus-
ration – national identity driving state policy – a more sia during the 1990s. To do this Abdelal proposes an
systematic framework through an examination of the alternative approach, one he terms ‘constructionism’,
nationalist sources of international economic integration. which ‘emphasizes non-material influences on both insti-
He argued for a decoupling of economic nationalism tutions and practices’ (Abdelal et al., 2010, p. 2). Rather
and protectionism by demonstrating how the core than states being autonomous actors that pursue an
nationalist aims of autonomy, unity and identity can objective self-interest, he suggests that they are ‘consen-
lead to both economic closure and openness. In an sually linked to society’ (Abdelal, 2001, p. 34). If eco-
interesting aside on the global impetus to a ‘free market nomic or any other types of policies are to be adopted
nationalism’,1 Shulman showed how the politics and by government, they must cohere with a shared national

Global Policy (2012) 3:3 ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Sam Pryke
284

identity. Although any group of societal actors can call pled in Abdelal’s work with discussion of the ideological
for a set of economic policies, they will only be enacted shifts in economic nationalism since 1945.
by the state if they correspond to public opinion. Thus, If these are the benefits of the new writing and think-
in Abdelal’s quasi-pluralist perspective, societal actors vie ing on economic nationalism, the case also has limita-
with one another in their access to government and tions and flaws. The first is that the definition of
influence on elites. economic nationalism is extremely vague. At times, the
This approach established, Abdelal proceeds to the argument rests on the assertion that as national identi-
empirical task of examining how national identities ties exist, so everything governments do with respect to
shaped the economic paths of post-Soviet states. With economics is ‘nationalist’. From this standpoint, it is diffi-
reference to trade agreements, currency use, etc., he cult to imagine what would not be included under the
contrasts the economic orientation of the Baltic States heading. A government that relinquishes all controls
away from Russia and towards Europe (at some immedi- over financial flows and privatises the entire public sec-
ate cost) with the direction taken by Belarus. In Belarus tor might be termed ‘economically nationalist’ so long
there were nationalists who sought to reduce the econ- as it claims that such moves are in the national interest.
omy’s reliance on Russia but, as they operated in the Such issues are seemingly in the mind of Helleiner and
context of a quite different national identity, one less Pickel (2005, p. 225) when they belatedly ask:
hostile to Russia, they could make little headway.
As his account develops and examples expand, Ab- If economic nationalism can be associated with
delal incorporates shifts in ideologies of development very diverse economic policies, does this mean
in explanation of a given economic nationalism, beside that economic nationalism is too vague a term
the inclination of a particular national identity. In dis- to be useful? No. Although its policy content
cussion of post-independence Indonesia, for instance, can be everything, economic nationalism
he shows how its statist economic path in the 1950s remains defined by its nationalism; this is asso-
coincided with Third Worldist currents of the era, a ciated with core nationalist values such as com-
markedly different climate from that of the 1990s. mitment to sovereignty.
National identities are therefore filtered through the
political economy of the age. As he puts it, ‘National- This is the first time in the book that the importance
ism has been linked to a wide variety of political pro- of sovereignty to nationalism is mentioned. We are left
jects; nationalism, in other words, is wanton’ (Abdelal, to wonder what the writers consider sovereignty to be
2001, p. 195). and, given the title, whether economic globalisation is
This approach to economic nationalism of scholars of undermining it.
international political economy (IPE) is clearly more ver- Second, although the sphere of economic nationalism
satile than that of either economic liberals or interna- is extended in recent writings, there is very little cover-
tional relations realists. With respect to the former, the age of the role of private capital. The assumption is that
understanding is that the intrusion of nationalist govern- states continue to be the key economic actors and states
ments into markets is explicable but counterproductive. promulgate national identity. Now we did not need
With the latter, the assumption is that there must be an recent bailouts and stimulus packages to make nonsense
overriding objectivity to an economic nationalism as it of the claims of so-called ‘hyperglobalists’ in the 1990s
corresponds to a state interest. Both analyses tend to that the state has become an irrelevance to capitalism
identify protectionism through tariffs and subsidy as the (Held, 1999, pp. 2–10). But one of the key points about
primary forms of economic nationalism. The rethinking globalisation is that private capital, in the form of multi-
of these conceptions and policy corollaries allows the national companies, has increasing discretion over which
importance of culture and memory, the stuff of nations, country it will invest in. In doing so, in jumping and con-
into understanding the economic policies of govern- sequently wearing down the walls of national econo-
ments. This is not to say that we can thus fathom the mies, it undermines the ability of the state to practise
irrational depths of an atavistic force. That, for instance, some form of ‘economic nationalism’, more specifically
the Baltic States might seek to reduce their economic national economic management. Third, there is little con-
dependence on Russia was perfectly explicable given sideration of how international economic organisations –
their 20th-century history. Further, the new analysis of the WTO, the World Bank and the International Monetary
economic nationalism, specifically in the work of Shul- Fund (IMF) – are empowered to impose economic dereg-
man (2000), enables understanding of the role played by ulation on states, regardless of whether they consider
nonstate actors like diasporas in economic policy. Finally, the measures to be in their national interest or not.
and of major importance, this approach can explain why Finally, there is no discussion of whether government
overtly nationalist governments have aggressively pur- policy across the world broadly conforms to a similar
sued pro-market agendas over recent history. This is cou- neoliberal trajectory. It is now 23 years since the term

ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:3
Economic Nationalism
285

‘Washington Consensus’ was first used to describe the sures – a particular form of economic nationalism – is
core measures – low tax, privatisation, financial deregula- itself explicable within the wider material and ideological
tion, etc. – that governments of both left and right are stage of capitalism, as we will now examine.
obliged to accept. Arguably, these writings are not, in
fact, so much about economic nationalism as much as
The history of economic nationalism
the nationalist motivation of economic policy. The point
is not a semantic one, it is crucial. Nationalism is indeed There are policy similarities in the mercantilism of Euro-
wanton as Abdelal puts it. Every student of the subject is pean states between the 16th and 18th centuries and
struck by its enormous power precisely because of its economic nationalism in the 19th century. However, as
extraordinary flexibility. It can motivate in different guises Greenfeld (2001, pp. 107–114) argues, there are difficul-
a varied range of policy objectives. With respect to eco- ties in designating mercantilism as an early nationalism
nomics, they can range from deregulation to national as the wellbeing of the country was rarely considered as
autarchy. It is pointless to try to establish whether or not distinct from the self-interest of individual merchant(s)
in principle a particular set of policies are more or less in and the collaborating monarchy involved. The explicit
line with ‘autonomy, unity and identity’. That is a politi- attempt to frame macroeconomic government policy on
cal matter for a nationalist leader and supporters in a behalf of the nation only arises in the 19th century. Most
given country at a particular conjuncture. self-declared national spokesmen in the early to mid-
Given this, I suggest that the definition of ‘economic 19th century supported free trade because of its general
nationalism’, as opposed to the nationalist motivation of association with liberation and advancement. It was the
economic policy, should be more limited and historically unacknowledged national bias in the advocacy of free
confined. Economic nationalism should be considered as markets by British industrialists that stimulated reactions
a set of practices designed to create, bolster and protect in this period that should be termed economic national-
national economies in the context of world markets. The ism, as distinct from the nationalist motivation of politi-
practice is not necessarily antithetical to external eco- cal economy. Among them, we can identify those of
nomic activity, but it is opposed to allowing a nation’s Alexander Hamilton (1755–1804) in America and List
fortunes to be determined by world markets alone. The (1789–1846) in Europe as particularly important. The
policies have consisted of controls on imports to create political influence of Hamilton, whose nationalism was
domestic monopolies, on finance to fix currencies, on somewhat the more civic, was greater as he was US
capital to direct investment to priority sectors and Treasury Secretary in the 1790s, while List provided the
nationalisation to establish state-owned companies. In most substantial theoretical critique of laissez-faire, prin-
some instances the process went further: the nationalisa- cipally Adam Smith, his followers in Britain and Jean-
tion of foreign companies (especially in the exploitation Baptiste Say in France.
of natural resources, mining and oil), the reduction or In part, List advocated protectionism as a temporary
removal of foreign staff, the prevention of the repatria- measure to boost the growth of German infant indus-
tion of the profits of foreign capital, the taking of for- tries (List, 1909, p. 323). Simultaneously, he rejected the
eign-owned patents, the appropriation of fishing and cosmopolitan assumption that a nation is merely an
prospecting rights by extending offshore waters, the aggregate of people. Rather, drawing on Fichte, he sug-
expulsion or control of ethnic minorities with significant gested that a nation is a cultural reality with a peculiar
business interests, self-sufficiency in agriculture and, if history, character and language. On occasion, he pro-
possible, in steel production and heavy industry more posed that culture, industry and the state should form a
generally (Harris, 1990, p. 248). single ‘economy of the people’ (List, 1909, p. 132).
The policies deployed determined the relative eco- Although List died a broken man, convinced he was
nomic closure of the state in question. At the extreme, ignored, his ideas had some influence on policy makers
there is the pursuit of economic autarchy: economic iso- in the latter part of the 19th century, especially in
lation in the pursuit of self-sufficiency, sometimes involv- Germany. While there was no general departure from
ing an aggressive foreign policy to corral the labour and economic liberalism as trade grew spectacularly, govern-
raw materials of conquered lands. Autarchy should be ments in Europe, America and Japan made impatient
distinguished from dirigiste regimes in which states attempts to force industrialisation through piecemeal
played a central role in the 1930s but were not closed to tariff hikes, amid periodic crises and a rising tide of
trade, and developmentalist states after 1945 that used popular nationalist sentiment.
import substitution while stimulating the external sales If economic rivalry, as manifested in protectionism,
of domestic producers. These political economies differ, was partly responsible for the 1914–18 war, the period
in turn, from the managed economies of developed afterwards did not see an abandonment of a common
countries during the long postwar boom. The point at commitment to international trade. Despite enlarged and
which states attempted a particular set of policy mea- more interventionist states within Europe through war-

Global Policy (2012) 3:3 ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Sam Pryke
286

time expenditure, the immediate aftermath, a period in The turn was most explicit in Europe under fascist and
which the leading gentlemen of the victorious European authoritarian regimes from Germany, through its central
powers tried to turn back the clock to the pre-1914 era, belt, to the Mediterranean south. To the east stood the
witnessed chronic financial instability giving way to eco- Soviet Union which, for different ideological reasons, dis-
nomic boom among industrialised and semi-industria- avowed free markets. Even in areas of the world where
lised countries after 1925. By 1929 world trade was there was no official renunciation of the free market,
higher than it had been in 1913 and comprised a greater there were schemes to cope with its failure. The New
share of most national economies (Jones, 2005, p. 28). Deal under Roosevelt in America (1933–36) defined the
This made the subsequent collapse all the more dra- era. In Britain there was no equivalent of this massive
matic. The world’s economy contracted by a third programme of government works. Instead, British indus-
between 1929 and 1934. Trade declined by 60 per cent try increasingly relied on exports to protected colonial
within four years from the Wall Street stock market crash markets to sustain its sales. It was not until the postwar
of October 1929. Britain’s withdrawal from the gold stan- era that the ideas of John Maynard Keynes, as contained
dard, a cornerstone of free transactions, in September in his 1936 The General Theory of Employment, Interest
1931 marked the end of an era that, despite the ructions and Money (Keynes, 2007), found favour in government
of war, imperialism and revolution, had stretched over and Whitehall.
the previous hundred years. Therefore, despite diehard It is interesting to note that Keynes expressed a prefer-
advocates in the world of high finance, government and ence for economic nationalism in this period. While his
academia, the period after 1929 saw a fundamental shift writings had naturally focused on Britain in the 1920s, as
from the principles of economic liberalism. Hobsbawm a good economic liberal his chief concern was the bet-
comments (1994, pp. 94–95): terment of humanity per se, not a particular segment.
Speeches and writings made in 1933 reveal a national
To meet immediate, short term crisis, govern- allegiance at odds with a cosmopolitan commitment. He
ments had, as they saw it, to undermine the long spoke, for instance, of the quest for ‘national self-suffi-
term basis of a flourishing world economy. States ciency’ to allow a ‘well balanced and complete’ national
found themselves building increasingly high bar- life, allowing ‘English people to display the full range of
riers to protect their national markets and curren- their national aptitudes in mechanical invention and in
cies against the world economic hurricanes, agriculture; as well as preserving traditional ways of liv-
knowing quite well that this meant dismantling ing’. After linking various occupations to the breadth of
of the world system of multinational trade on the national character, he dismissed the notion that
which they believed world prosperity must rest accounts alone should determine economic viability:
… In a single sentence: the Great Slump ‘The country that cannot afford agriculture is deluded as
destroyed economic liberalism for half a century. to the meaning of the word ‘‘afford’’. A country that can-
not afford agriculture, or invention, or tradition, is a
The so-called ‘most favoured nation status’ disap- country in which one cannot afford to live’. While self-
peared from almost 60 per cent of the 510 commercial sufficiency was in itself desirable, its practical merit was
agreements signed between 1931 and 1939 and, where that an international division of labour linked by trade
it remained, it was usually in a limited form. By 1939 was no longer viable. Instead, he wanted to ‘bring pro-
almost half of world trade was restricted by tariffs ducer and consumer within the ambit of the same
(Jones, 2005, p. 28). national, economic and financial organisation’, and thus
The lurch away from economic liberalism after 1929 avoid the ‘strains and enmities’ that had led to war in
was not ordered, coherent and backed by theoretical 1914 (Keynes, in Skidelsky, 1992, pp. 473–474).
models. Instead, it was driven by immediate priorities Robert Skidelsky, Keynes’ biographer, comments that
and medium-term financial fault lines. Crucial to whether Keynes had moved from Smith to List to Dr Schacht who
a state moved directly towards greater economic isola- was in 1933 taking the levers of economic power in Nazi
tion in the early 1930s was its sovereign debt level. Such Germany (Skidelsky, 1992, p. 476). The comparison with
shifts were particularly pronounced in certain geographi- List is only half accurate because in part List only advo-
cal areas. Most economies within Latin America and the cated economic protection as a temporary measure. It is
advanced colonies of European empires, which relied on therefore indicative of how the intellectual climate had
agricultural and raw material exports, suspended the changed that an economic liberal of the 20th century
convertibility of their currencies and tried to stimulate was for a while more an economic nationalist than the
domestic alternatives to external markets. This involved most prominent critic of laissez-faire in the 19th century.
the expansion of industry by making costs exceptionally In the aftermath of the Second World War, an event
low and hence profits exceptionally high. Simulta- that had itself seen the state organisation of economies
neously, measures to restrict imports were introduced. on an unprecedented scale, differing models of political

ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:3
Economic Nationalism
287

economy emerged with underlying commonalities. The elite groups was that foreign investment was a good
general policy trajectory followed by the US, the leading thing, helpful to them and helpful to the country con-
state to emerge from the war, involved both a rejection cerned’. The postwar era saw a major reconsideration of
of unfettered free market capitalism and autarchy.2 For- this view among policy makers and thinkers. A new con-
mer Secretary of State Cordell Hull captured the Ameri- sensus emerged that national development could only
can approach when he claimed that for goods instead of be achieved by state intervention to correct inherent
soldiers to cross borders, the conscious administration of structural weaknesses, born of an overreliance on agri-
economies by governments was required (Frieden, 2005, culture and raw materials, sectors prone to market vola-
p. 254). American and British policy makers had, of tility and historic declines in value. Of course, there were
course, drawn up the institutional arrangements – cru- marked differences in the theory and practice of devel-
cially fixed exchange rates – for the postwar economic opmentalism. The best known development economist
order at Bretton Woods in 1944. in this period, Raul Prebisch (1901–86), was forced to
In Europe corporatism (the integration of business and leave his native Argentina in 1948, such were his dis-
labour through government), exemplified by the Labour agreements with the military government of Juan Peron.
government of Britain, 1945–51, and the Monnet Plan in His biographer comments: ‘Both were nationalists, but
France, 1945–47, was institutionalised through a set of they were radically different in style and ideology’ (Dos-
arrangements supported by the major political parties. man, 2008, p. 217).
Contemporaneous was the spread of nominally socialist By the 1960s an overview of Latin America (Wi-
countries under Soviet leadership to encompass by 1950 onczek, 1966, p. 17) could claim: ‘Government after
Eastern Europe and China. While trade and some travel government in Latin America, almost independently of
existed between them, their economies relied on the its political colouring, discourages the entry of new for-
planned investment and distribution of ruling Com- eign private capital and uses numerous legal strata-
munist parties. gems to diminish the relative role of existing foreign
Both the US and Western European variants of man- direct investment in certain fields’. Restriction on for-
aged capitalism were, in part, designed to offset the eign companies existed not simply in industry and min-
appeal of communism in the mid-20th century. But this ing but banking and insurance, radio and motion
did not mean that the example of Soviet planning was pictures among others. This was accompanied by out-
lost on policy makers – Hobsbawm refers to a ‘small but right expropriation of foreign companies, the nationali-
influential flow of socio-economic tourists to Moscow’ sation of Mexican oilfields in 1938 being the first
(Hobsbawm, 1994, p. 96) – even if they were avowed instance. The cumulative results for some investor
anti-communists. Rather, the spectacular growth of countries were dramatic. Britain lost 40 per cent of its
industrial output in the 1930s, coupled with the wartime total overseas business assets – more in Asia and Africa
role of the USSR in defeating Nazi Germany, made for than Latin America – between 1938–56 through seques-
grudging recognition that, whatever the political horrors tration, wartime destruction of property and obligatory
of Stalin, the Soviet economy was superior in crucial sales (Jones, 2005, p. 244).
respects to free market capitalism. Leaders of some Space does not allow examination of the degree of
developing countries admired Soviet industrialisation variation with respect to export promotion of developing
even when they rejected communism as a system. countries in this period; suffice it to say that import sub-
This era witnessed the sustained attempt to develop stitution did not necessarily militate against it. Speaking
and diversify national economies across Asia, Africa and of the South Korean economy in the 1960s and 1970s,
Latin America. It was not an accompaniment to formal Ohno (2004, p. 139) claims: ‘Export promotion policies
political independence but fundamental to it, an intrinsic and import-substitution policies, which are often consid-
part of national liberation. Harris (1986, p. 159) suggests ered to be mutually exclusive, in fact coexisted through-
that the key development policy of import substitution out the period in question’. The same was true of
to force industrialisation in the postwar era had already Mexico and Brazil, among others.
been introduced in the 1930s, a response compelled by This phase of economic nationalism lasted until the
the collapse of export markets. Further, Eastern Euro- 1980s, becoming a normal feature of the world. Most
pean intellectuals in the 1930s – Mandelbaum, Balogh, developing countries in Asia, Africa and Latin America
Kaldor, Manilesco – formulated many of the key claims became progressively more closed to international trade
in development economics in Latin America and else- and even the richest economies maintained very high
where after 1945. tariffs for agricultural imports, far higher than before
Nevertheless, these facts should not detract from the 1913 (Jones, 2005, p. 32). The liberalisation that the Gen-
shift involved. Vernon comments on Latin America (1971, eral Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) achieved in
p. 191): ‘Through the nineteenth century to the early the 1960s was actually reversed after the abrupt end of
part of the twentieth century, the prevailing view among the post war boom in 1973.

Global Policy (2012) 3:3 ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Sam Pryke
288

Simultaneously, total export sales as a percentage of grammes imposed by the IMF on the key countries of
world output grew by nearly 8 per cent p.a. for the per- Malaysia, Indonesia and Thailand reveal that the rollback
iod 1950–73, higher than the 5 per cent average annual of protectionism and activist state intervention were stra-
rise in output as a whole. The economic turbulence of tegically incorporated into them’.
the late 1970s and early 1980s did not check the momen- In fact, these events did not prompt anything that
tum of international trade and finance as, measured by amounts to economic nationalism. In the aftermath of
key indices, they actually accelerated. In every year, the the 1997 crash, the Malaysian prime minister, Mahathir
growth in exports continued to outstrip the modest over- Mohammad, made a number of high-profile attacks on
all rise in world output. Between 1970 and 1990, exports international financiers (especially George Soros), sacked
as a proportion of total world output doubled. Politically and charged his finance minister, Anwar Ibrahim, who
and intellectually, the 1980s saw a marked shift away was responsible for economic liberalisation, and imposed
from the economic ideas associated with Keynes in the capital and currency controls on Malaysia. However, as
developed world, and with Prebisch and others in devel- Frieden (2005, p. 394) comments:
oping countries. Instead, a new breed of right-wing politi-
cians, exemplified by Margaret Thatcher in Britain and In another era the vitriolic Mahathir–Soros
Ronald Reagan in America, made reference to Milton exchanges and the Malaysian prime minister’s
Freedman and Frederick von Hayek in attempts to curb nationalistic rhetoric might have presaged long-
the money supply (monetarism), shackle trade unions lasting measures to turn the economy away
and liberalise markets. This trend had been presaged by from global markets. Yet within a couple of
General Pinochet’s military coup in Chile in 1973 and the years the episode had largely been forgotten …
deregulation of the ‘Chicago boys’. Mahathir was indeed careful to avoid blanket
The 1980s culminated with the vindication of capital- condemnation of global capitalism. ‘We want to
ism through the revolutions of Eastern Europe in 1989 embrace borderlessness’, he said and ‘We have
and the unravelling of the Soviet Union. From 1992 always welcomed foreign investment and spec-
through to 2005, the ratio of trade to GDP across richer ulation’. It was just that ‘we still need to protect
countries increased by some 13 per cent (OECD, 2007). ourselves from self-serving rogues and interna-
The 1990s was the decade in which the very term ‘glob- tional brigandage’ … Despite the great shock
alisation’ became a catchall for the market integration that international markets administered to the
that had taken place over the previous 40 years. East Asian economies and the wave of crises
Of course, to indicate a decisive transformation in the that the shock caused, the advance of global
world’s economy is not to suggest that complete eco- economic integration was barely slowed.
nomic globalisation had been achieved by October 2008.
Leaving aside the impact of the subsequent recession, However, the threat to economic globalisation of the
economic globalisation is uneven and limited by the recession of 2008–09 was of a different order. Triggered
extent of the integration of national economies, its inter- by the ‘credit crunch’, following the collapse of the US
national reach and continuing tariff barriers, national and subprime mortgage market in 2007, the banking crash
regional with respect to the European Union. As Wolf of October 2008 and the subsequent recession are the
(2004, p. 134), not a sceptic given to playing down its products of a 30-year experiment in financial deregula-
extent, put it in 2004, ‘Globalization is not rampant. It tion. The brazen financial irresponsibility involved, the
remains remarkably modest’. However, the political and credo of the financialisation of key economies, was con-
economic environment produced by the latest wave of doned by governments and induced by a wider faith
globalisation is rather different from its first phase in the that markets, as self-regulating entities, are infallible –
19th century. This is the backdrop to examine the pros- what Soros (2004) termed ‘market fundamentalism’.
pect of a resurgent economic nationalism at the present Relevant for our purposes is the impact the financial
conjuncture. crisis has had on world trade. A dramatic fall in demand
saw trade volumes collapse by 12.2 per cent in 2009 (23
per cent in US dollar terms), much the largest contrac-
Prospects
tion since the 1930s (WTO, 2010). Over the ten years
As indicated above, it is not difficult to find predictions before the crash, trade grew on average by 5.7 per cent
of a return to economic nationalism. For instance, there p.a. This fall was not, as widely expected, repeated in
was speculation that the Asian crash of 1997–98 would 2010 as it grew by 9.5 per cent and a similar figure in
see a nationalist reaction as the World Bank and the IMF 2011. The exports of China and India have suffered least
sought to use the opportunity to open protected Asian over the last four years.
economies and overvalued currencies to world markets. The financial crisis did prompt some governments to
Bello comments (2004, p. 73) that ‘the stabilization pro- introduce protectionist measures. The Economist (2009c)

ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:3
Economic Nationalism
289

reported: ‘The World Bank has counted 47 trade-restrict- Second, the very complexity of the global economy,
ing steps taken by 17 of the G20 members. Tariffs have specifically the multinational company or bank with its
risen in several developing countries, including India, intricacies of ownership, outsourcing and intrafirm trade
Russia and Ecuador’. Simultaneously, there were indica- (as much as half of MNC activity in 2000 according to
tions of political pressure to keep government financial one authority – Jones, 2005, p. 272), make it all but
injections within domestic economies. However, this did impossible to pick apart by nationality. This was revealed
not give way to systematic hikes on import tariffs. The when government stimulus packages to domestic finan-
number of trade-restricting measures applied by govern- cial firms actually benefited foreign banks (Callinicos,
ments has actually declined since 2009. WTO Director 2010, p. 103). Thus the American AIG paid $18 billion to
General Pascal Lamy could boast (WTO, 2010): European securities lending counterparts – Barclays,
‘WTO rules and principles have assisted governments in Deutsche Bank and BNP Paribas – of the $180 billion fed-
keeping markets open and they now provide a platform eral government bailout in March 2009. With respect to
from which trade can grow as the global economy industrial stimulus, the question arose of just what exists
improves’, before adding: ‘We must avoid derailing any that counts as national. For instance, the foreign-owned
economic revival through protectionism’. Predictions UK car industry received considerable government aid
about the longer-term future would be foolish, but it over 2009. No one objected that foreign capitalists bene-
seems clear that the recession has not developed into a fited, save some marginal voices on the far right. Where
prolonged slump and there has been no clear reversal in there still is a domestic car industry in Europe the situa-
economic globalisation. And there is evidence that the tion was not necessarily clearer. The German govern-
impact of protectionism on trade in 2009 was negligible. ment’s insistence that there should be no job losses in
Research by Christian Henn and Brad McDonald of the Opel, General Motors’ German brand, complicated the
International Monetary Fund (Financial Times 2011) lead rival bids of Fiat, Magna and RHJ for the ailing US giant’s
the authors to conclude: ‘Our estimate of a 0.25 per cent European subsidiaries.
protectionist distortion confirms that protectionism Third, there is less of a possibility of enacting protec-
played only a minor role in the Great Trade Collapse at tionism within zones of the world economy as in, say,
end-2008’. colonial empires in the 1930s. Now, of course, globalisa-
Of course, to say that there has been no ‘return to the tion is, in part, the story of greater regional trade and
1930s’ is not in itself particularly profound. It is question- investment (Held, 1999, p. 168). However, such is the
able how likely it was that events would unfold in the importance of interregional business within a single
same way with emergency measures followed by a sus- world economy that there is no scope for the world
tained attempt to realign economic activity within dividing along geographic or political lines. The extent
national boundaries. The calls of journalists, politicians of trade and financial flows between China and the US
and capitalists that there should be no return to protec- and Europe are well known. What is less well known is
tionism and so on were rhetorical, rather than analysis- that China is Brazil’s biggest trading partner through the
based projections. Nevertheless, the conjuncture allows sales of commodities and the purchase of manufactures
us the opportunity to reflect on why there has been no (Anderson, 2011, p. 11). This is the background to Brazil
real attempt by governments to withdraw national econ- under Lula joining with China as well as India and Russia
omies from world markets. in the so-called BRIC quartet in 2009. Their objective,
There are various interrelated reasons. First, the inte- however, is a global reserve currency, not a detached
gration and therefore interdependency of economies trading block. The fallout from the financial crisis in the
through trade and investment make this practically world’s most advanced regional organisation and market,
impossible. In 2008 exports of products and services the European Union, has been greater disunity as leaders
averaged just under 60 per cent of GDP internationally of northern member states, especially Germany, have,
(OECD, 2011). In a considerable number of both devel- with great reluctance, bailed out the most indebted
oped economies (e.g. Austria, Belgium, Singapore) and economies of the continent’s south. Nobody has sug-
developing ones (e.g. Angola, Malaysia, Vietnam) the fig- gested an economic ‘fortress Europe’.
ure was well over 100 per cent. Even for the relatively Fourth, the various models of economic nationalism, of
introverted Japanese economy the figure was 35 per sets of practices designed to create, bolster and protect
cent. Raising tariff barriers, provoking retaliation and risk- national economies in the context of world markets, are
ing a large-scale reversal in trading levels would not discredited. We saw in the 1930s that temporary mea-
have seen a mere slump but an economic Armageddon. sures designed to cope with the financial crash, as much
The point could be extended through examination of as recognition of the system’s flaws, undermined the
the expansion of foreign direct investment and the per- basis of economic liberalism. This gelled with an intellec-
centage of domestic workforces employed by foreign tual shift away from free market capitalism. The statist
companies. shift went furthest in fascist and communist regimes but

Global Policy (2012) 3:3 ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Sam Pryke
290

was common across the political spectrum, leaving free Conclusions


market ideologues as isolated academic voices after 1945.
This article has attempted to define, historically situate
Today there is no such intellectual move afoot. No less an
and discuss the continuing relevance of economic
authority than the Financial Times ran a series of articles
nationalism. The present conjuncture presents a timely
on the ‘survival of capitalism’ in March 2009, but this has
moment for doing so as, contrary to much speculation,
not developed into a mainstream rethink on the relation-
the financial crash of October 2008 and the subsequent
ship of state and market. The importance of the former
recession have not seen a generalised rise in economic
has been underlined over the last three years, but only to
protectionism. The article first examined the contention
bail out private capitalism – thereby accumulating mas-
that economic nationalism amounts to protectionism, a
sive deficits – not as a mechanism that replaces the mar-
view that contrasts with the opinion of a number of
ket’s central role. There have been some ill coordinated
scholars of international economy. They suggest that our
moves to reregulate the banks, but this hardly amounts
definition of economic nationalism should be far broader
to economic nationalism. Arguably, in fact, neoliberalism
than a particular set of state policies – tariffs, etc. It was
has been strengthened over the last three years, some-
suggested that, although this new scholarship provides
thing furthered by the ongoing crossover of personnel
important insights, it is actually more concerned with
between high finance and states, a particular feature of
the nationalist motivation of economic policy. Instead,
Wall Street and American federal government.
economic nationalism should be understood as the
In this context it is relevant to consider what is now
attempt to create, bolster and protect national econo-
the most indebted nation in the world, the Republic of
mies in the context of world markets.
Ireland. Irish sovereign debt of 1305 per cent of GDP fol-
Using this definition, we saw how economic national-
lowing enormous bank bailouts has given rise to much
ism arose in the 19th century and became central to
acrimony, but no political attempt to withdraw the econ-
state economic organisation in the mid-20th century.
omy from the global economic networks in which it is
However, in the period after 1945 the accelerating
so entwined. None of the major political parties in the
growth of market integration through trade and finance
February 2011 election called for a withdrawal from the
undermined the reality and ideology of national econo-
euro, a suspension of debt repayments or even the gen-
mies. The financial crash of 2008 necessitated massive
eration of extra revenue through higher tariffs or raising
state aid to domestic banks and industry, but the
the 12.5 per cent tax rate for foreign business. Some
endeavour has been to allow the continued impetus of
older Irish people may recall the closed Catholic Ireland
economic globalisation, not a major reconsideration or
of Éamon de Valera with nostalgia, but anyone suggest-
reversal. Of course, the turbulence of capitalism will con-
ing a return to national self-sufficiency (mythical given
tinue to stimulate political reactions, nationalist and
the importance of dairy exports to Britain and emigrant
other, but this is rather different from what can be prop-
remittances) would be thought a fool.
erly called ‘economic nationalism’.
The political consensus of ‘no alternative’ was threa-
tened by the emergence of a hitherto marginal left wing
political party, Syriza, prepared to withdraw from the Notes
euro, in the June 2012 Greek general election. In fact,
I would like to thank audiences who first heard a version of this
the centre right New Democracy party received the most article at the ASEN conference at the LSE, April 2009 and the ESA
votes and has since succeeded in forming a coalition conference in Lisburn, September 2009. Particular thanks are due to
government. Greek politics remains uncertain given the the three constructive reviewers who made helpful comments on
intractable economic crisis, but it is worth pointing out the initial submission of the article to Global Policy.
that even in a country experiencing acute social break- 1. There are related, more specific, terms that generate concern,
down, there has as yet been no break with an orthodox principally ‘resource nationalism’ and now ‘financial nationalism’.
government. Moreover, whatever challenge a possible 2. The term ‘free market nationalism’ is one used by writers on
Syriza future government might mean for the stability of stateless nations in discussion of whether they might exist as via-
the euro zone, its programme is not that of a traditional ble independent entities (Keating, 2001).
‘left nationalist’ type. 3. It was as late as 1973 that Richard Nixon declared: ‘We are all
Keynesians now’.
Finally, it is worth mentioning that although the after-
math of the global financial crash has not seen states
resolve longstanding disagreements over the imbalances
in the world’s economy, an enlarged G20 organisation References
did succeed in temporarily uniting world leaders when
Abdelal, R. (2001) National Purpose in the World Economy: Post-
faced with a collapse of trade and a sharp fall in indus- Soviet States in Comparative Perspective. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Uni-
trial output after October 2008. As indicated above, pro- versity Press.
tection has actually receded somewhat since that period.

ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. Global Policy (2012) 3:3
Economic Nationalism
291

Abdelal, R., Blyth, M. and Parsons, C. (eds) (2010) Constructing the James, H. (2001) The End of Globalization: Lessons from the Great
International Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Depression. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Anderson, B. (1998) The Spectre of Comparison. London: Verso. Jones, G. (2005) Multinational Companies and Global Capitalism.
Anderson, P. (2011) ‘Lula’s Brazil’, The London Review of Books, 33 Oxford: Oxford University Press.
(7), pp. 3–12. Keating, M. (2001) Nations against the State: The New Politics of
Bello, W. (2004) Deglobalization: Ideas for a New World Economy, Nationalism in Quebec, Catalonia and Scotland, second edition.
second edition. London: Zed Books. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan.
Cable, V. (2008) ‘The Rise of Economic Nationalism’, New Statesman, Keynes, J. M. (2007) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
16 October. Available from: http://www.newstatesman.com/busi- Money. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
ness/2008/10/economic-nationalism-state [Accessed 12 March List, F. (1909) The National System of Political Economy, trans. S.
2011]. Lloyd. London: Longman.
Callinicos, A. (2010) Bonfire of the Illusions. Cambridge: Polity Mayall, J. (1990) Nationalism and International Society. Cambridge:
Press. Cambridge University Press.
Crane, G. T. (1998) ‘Economic Nationalism: Bringing the Nation Back Nakano, T. (2004) ‘Theorising Economic Nationalism’, Nations and
In’, Millennium, 27 (1), pp. 55–75. Nationalism, 10 (3), pp. 211–229.
Dosman, E. (2008) The Life and Times of Raul Prebisch, 1901–1986. O’Brien, R. and Williams, M. (2007) Global Political Economy, Evolution
Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press. and Dynamics, third edition. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan.
The Economist (2009a) ‘The Return of Economic Nationalism’, 5 Feb- Ohno, K. (2004) ‘Development Strategy and the Role of Government
ruary. Available from: http://www.economist.com/node/ Policies: Reconsidering the E. Asia Experience’, in A. Koshaka
13061443 [Accessed 8 February 2011]. (ed.), New Development Strategies: Beyond the Washington Con-
The Economist (2009b) ‘Turning their Back on the World’, 19 Febru- sensus. London: Palgrave, pp. 218–239.
ary. Available from: http://www.economist.com/node/13145370? Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)
story_id=13145370 [Accessed 8 February 2011]. (2007) Factbook. Available from: http://fiordiliji.sourceoecd.org/
The Economist (2009c) ‘Going Under’, 24 March. Available from: vl=6449432/cl=26/nw=1/rpsv/factbook/ [Accessed 14 March 2011].
http://www.economist.com/node/13355727?story_- Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)
id=E1_TPPVVSNS [Accessed 8 February 2011]. (2011) Statistics. Available from: http://www.oecd.org/document/
Financial Times (2011) ‘World trade: Frothy rhetoric of currency ‘war’ 0,3746,en_2649_201185_46462759_1_1_1_1,00.html [Accessed
unmatched by reality’, 25 January. Available from: http://www. 14 March 2011].
ft.com/cms/s/0/d7f1a49e-273f-11e0-80d7-0144feab49a.html#axzz Shulman, S. (2000) ‘Nationalist Sources of International Integration’,
1yuJFolKB [Accessed 26 June 2012] International Studies Quarterly, 44 (3), pp. 365–390.
Frieden, J. A. (2005) Global Capitalism: Its Rise and Fall in the Twenti- Skidelsky, R. (1992) John Maynard Keynes, Vol. 2: The Economist as
eth Century. London: W. W. Norton. Saviour 1920–1937. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Gilpin, R. (1987) The Political Economy of International Relations. Smith, A. D. (1995) Nations in a Global Era. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Smith, A. D. (1998) Nationalism and Modernism: A Critical Survey of
Gilpin, R. (2001) Global Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Recent Theories of Nations and Nationalism. London: Routledge.
University Press. Soros, G. (2004) George Soros on Globalization. New York: Public
Greenfeld, L. (2001) The Spirit of Capitalism: Nationalism and Eco- Affairs.
nomic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Vernon, R. (1971) Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of US
The Guardian (2012) ‘World Bank warns that euro collapse could spark Enterprises. London: Penguin.
global crisis’, 16 June. Available from: http://www.guardian.co.uk/ Wionczek, M. (1966) ‘A Latin American View’, in R. Vernon (ed.),
business/2012/jun/16/world-bank-euro-collapse-crisis?INTCMP= How Latin America Views the US Investor. New York: Praeger, pp.
SRCH [Accessed 26 June 2012] 5–14.
Harris, N. (1986) The End of the Third World: Newly Industrializing Wolf, M. (2004) Why Globalization Works. New Haven, CT: Yale Uni-
Countries and the Decline of an Ideology. London: Penguin. versity Press.
Harris, N. (1990) National Liberation. London: I. B. Tauris. World Trade Organization (WTO) (2010) ‘Trade to Expand by 9.5%
Held, D. (1999) Global Transformations: Politics, Economics and Cul- in 2010 after a Dismal 2009, WTO Reports’, Press Release, 26
ture. Cambridge: Polity Press. March. Available from: http://www.wto.org/english/news_e/pres
Helleiner, E. and Pickel, A. (eds) (2005) Economic Nationalism in a 10_e/pr598_e.htm [Accessed 14 March 2011].
Globalizing World. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Hobsbawm, E. (1992) Nations and Nationalism since 1780: Pro-
gramme, Myth and Reality, second edition. Cambridge: Cam- Author Information
bridge University Press.
Sam Pryke, PhD, now teaches Sociology at Wolverhampton
Hobsbawm, E. (1994) The Age of Extremes: The Short Twentieth Cen-
University.
tury. London: Michael Joseph.

Global Policy (2012) 3:3 ª 2012 London School of Economics and Political Science and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

También podría gustarte