Está en la página 1de 4

Economic Brief

March 2017, EB17-03

Are the Effects of Monetary Policy Asymmetric?


By Regis Barnichon, Christian Matthes, and Tim Sablik

The Federal Reserve uses monetary policy to stimulate the economy when
unemployment is high and to rein in inflationary pressures when the econ-
omy is overheating. However, evidence suggests that these policy stances
have unequal effects. Contractionary monetary shocks raise unemployment
more strongly than expansionary shocks lower it.

The Federal Reserve has a dual mandate to policies during the Great Recession after reduc-
maintain stable prices and maximum sustain- ing its target rate to nearly zero seemed to have
able employment. It does so primarily by con- little effect on unemployment.
trolling its target interest rate (the federal funds
rate), which influences short-term market rates. Monetary policy asymmetry is best described
When unemployment is elevated, the Fed loos- using a metaphor. Imagine a string with mon-
ens monetary policy (lowers its target rate) to etary policy at one end and the economy at the
stimulate economic activity and boost output. other. Employing tight monetary policy when
When inflation is rising, the Fed tightens policy inflation is rising is like pulling on the string to
(raises its target rate) to slow economic activity keep the economy in check it works fairly
and counteract inflationary pressure. well. But attempting to stimulate the economy
with loose policy during a downturn is like try-
But are both types of policy responses equally ing to push on the string to move the economy
effective? Since the Great Depression, econo- not very effective.
mists have suspected that tight policy may
have a stronger effect on output than loose In addition to monetary changes having asym-
policy because the Feds response to the market metric effects based on their direction, the
crash of 1929 failed to avert the Great Depres- strength of monetary policy may also vary with
sion. Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz later the state of the economy. Previous tests for mon-
argued in their 1963 book, A Monetary History of etary policy asymmetries have had somewhat
the United States, that this was because the Feds mixed results, but this Economic Brief presents
policy stance during the early 1930s actually new evidence to confirm the asymmetric effects
was contractionary rather than expansionary, of monetary policy.
but other examples have reinforced the view
that expansionary monetary policy may be more Why Might Monetary Policy Be Asymmetric?
limited than contractionary policy. Most recently, There are several theoretical reasons why mon-
the Fed was forced to turn to unconventional etary policy could have asymmetric effects on

EB17-03 - Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Page 1


economic output.1 The first relates to the behavior Testing for Asymmetry
of lenders and borrowers under different monetary If monetary policy does have asymmetric effects on
conditions. When the Fed raises its policy rates, mar- output, that finding would have important implica-
ket rates tend to rise accordingly. One might expect tions for how the Fed conducts policy. Conclusive
that banks would simply pass these higher rates on to evidence one way or the other has proven some-
their borrowers. While this is true to an extent, raising what elusive, however. A number of studies do find
loan rates too high could increase the likelihood that evidence that contractionary policy has a stronger
risky borrowers default. As a result, banks may choose effect on output than expansionary policy, as the
to ration credit during a period of high interest rates, theory predicts.2 But other studies find that what
constraining credit for some consumers and leading matters is not the direction of the monetary change
to a bigger decline in output, thus amplifying the but rather its size.3 And still other studies find evi-
impact of contractionary monetary policy. On the dence that the impact of monetary policy depends
other hand, expansionary policy will not necessarily chiefly on the state of the economy.4
increase borrowing and spending if economic condi-
tions have reduced demand. Unlike tight monetary One problem facing economists trying to find evi-
policy, it is not a binding constraint on consumers (as dence of asymmetry is that the standard models
expressed in the old adage, you can lead a horse to used for measuring the effects of shocks, such as
water but you cant make it drink). changes in monetary policy, have difficulty identify-
ing asymmetric effects. Economists have attempted
Another reason why expansionary monetary policy to get around this problem in two ways. The first
might be less effective than contractionary policy involves looking at unanticipated increases and
is because prices seem less likely to adjust down- decreases in the money supply and testing whether
ward that is, they are sticky. Firms also may be these changes have asymmetric effects. One chal-
reluctant to lower wages for fear of damaging worker lenge with this approach is correctly identifying
morale. Because of such downward price and wage unanticipated monetary shocks. Additionally, while
rigidity, firms will tend to respond to contraction- these models may be able to detect asymmetry
ary monetary policy by reducing output rather than based on the direction of a monetary change,
prices. Prices and wages are less upwardly sticky, they struggle to measure other potential causes of
however. Firms are accustomed to raising prices and asymmetry. Another approach makes use of regime-
wages gradually due to inflation, for example. As a switching models that allow for the impact of one
result, expansionary monetary policy is more likely variable (monetary policy) to depend upon changes
to prompt a change in prices rather than output. in another variable (the state of the economy). But
while these models can identify whether the effects
Finally, monetary policy may have asymmetric effects of monetary policy change with the business cycle,
during different points in the business cycle due to they are not able to determine if the effects of con-
changes in consumer outlook. Similar to the credit- tractionary policy are inherently different from
constraint argument, if consumers are pessimistic those of expansionary policy.
about economic conditions, then lowering rates may
not do much to stimulate borrowing and spending. Two of the authors of this brief, Barnichon and Mat-
This explanation is not entirely compelling, however, thes, have developed an alternative approach for
since consumer optimism during a boom period addressing these issues.5 They start with a model
should also weaken the effect of tight monetary of the economy in which the behavior of a system
policy. For contractionary policy to have a stronger of macroeconomic variables is determined by its
effect than expansionary policy, consumers and firms (possibly asymmetric) response to past and present
would have to be more pessimistic during economic shocks. They then use Gaussian functions to para-
downturns than they are optimistic during booms. meterize the dynamic effects of structural shocks
This is certainly possible but perhaps not realistic. on the economy. The advantage of this approach

Page 2
dubbed Gaussian Mixture Approximation is hand, a 0.7 percentage point decrease in the federal
that it uses only a small set of free parameters, which funds rate produces only a 0.04 percentage point de-
then allows for a much more efficient estimation of crease in unemployment an effect that is not
models with asymmetric responses. In simulations, statistically different from zero. This implies that
Barnichon and Matthes approach not only performs contractionary monetary policy has a significantly
as well as benchmark models in estimating linear or stronger effect on unemployment than expansion-
symmetric responses, it can also detect asymmetric ary policy.
responses in nonlinear models. Barnichon and Mat-
thes use their new methodology to estimate wheth- Barnichon and Matthes also find some, albeit incon-
er monetary shocks generate asymmetric responses clusive, evidence that prices respond asymmetrically
depending on the direction of the shock as well as to monetary changes. Prices appear stickier follow-
the state of the economy. ing monetary contractions than following monetary
expansions. This provides some supporting evidence
Results and Implications for the theory that monetary policy has asymmetric
Barnichon and Matthes first test whether the direc- effects because firms are more reluctant to lower
tion of a monetary shock alone results in different prices and wages than to raise them.
economic responses. Applying data from 1959
through 2007 to their model, they find strong evi- Next, Barnichon and Matthes expand their model
dence of an asymmetric response in unemployment to allow the effects of monetary policy to depend
depending on the direction of the monetary change. on both the direction of the change and the state
They estimate that an increase in the federal funds of the economy. Again, they find that expansionary
rate of 0.7 percentage points results in an increase in monetary policy has a weaker effect on unemploy-
unemployment of 0.15 percentage points, a larger ment than contractionary policy. Additionally, they
effect than the 0.10 percentage points estimated by find that the effect of expansionary policy depends
a standard linear model.6 (See Figure 1.) On the other on the state of the economy. When unemployment

Figure 1: Asymmetric Unemployment Rate Responses to Monetary Policy Changes


Contractionary Monetary Shock Expansionary Monetary Shock
Contractionary Monetary Shock Expansionary Monetary Shock
0.2
0.20 0.2
0.20
Percentage Point Increase in Unemployment

Percentage Point Decrease in Unemployment


Percentage Point Decrease in Unemployment Rate
Percentage Point Increase in Unemployment Rate

0.15
0.15 0.15
0.15

0.1
0.10 0.1
0.10

0.05
0.05 0.05
0.05

00 00

-0.05
-0.05 -0.05
-0.05
11 55 9 13 17 21 25 29 1 5 99 13
13 17
17 21
21 25
25 29
29
Quarters since Shock
Quarters Since Shock Quarters since Shock
Quarters Since Shock
Barnichon and Matthes Standard Linear Model
Barnichon and Matthes Barnichon and Matthes
Source: Regis Barnichon and Christianmodel
Standard Matthes, Gaussian Mixture Approximations of Impulse ResponsesStandard
and the Nonlinear
modelEffects of Monetary
Shocks, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 16-08, June 2016.
Notes: Shaded areas represent margins of error above and below Barnichon and Matthes estimates. These areas account for 90 percent of all cases.

Page 3
is low, expansionary policy generates a substantial 3
F or example, Morten O. Ravn and Martin Sola, A Reconsidera-
tion of the Empirical Evidence on the Asymmetric Effects of
increase in inflation but little change in unemploy-
Money-Supply Shocks: Positive vs. Negative or Big vs. Small?
ment. When unemployment is high, expansionary Birkbeck, University of London, Archive Discussion Paper No.
monetary policy has little effect on inflation and 9606, February 1996.
some positive effect on employment. This is consis- 4
F or example, see Silvana Tenreyro and Gregory Thwaites,
tent with standard macroeconomic theory and the Pushing on a String: US Monetary Policy Is Less Powerful in
Feds experience during the Great Inflation. Recessions, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics,
October 2016, vol. 8, no. 4, pp. 4374. A working paper ver-
sion is available online. Also, see Ming Chien Lo and Jeremy
The findings from Barnichon and Matthes model Piger, Is the Response of Output to Monetary Policy Asym-
have a number of implications for monetary policy- metric? Evidence from a Regime-Switching Coefficients Model,
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, October 2005, vol. 37,
makers. They suggest that monetary policy asym-
no. 5, pp. 865886. A working paper version is available online.
metries may be larger than previous estimates have Also, see Charles L. Weise, The Asymmetric Effects of Monetary
found. The Feds ability to stimulate the economy Policy: A Nonlinear Vector Autoregression Approach, Journal
through expansionary policy appears less potent of Money, Credit and Banking, February 1999, vol. 31, no. 1,
pp. 85108.
than the negative effect contractionary policy has
on employment. Additionally, as theory and other
5
R
 egis Barnichon and Christian Matthes, Gaussian Mixture Ap-
proximations of Impulse Responses and the Nonlinear Effects
studies have suggested, attempting to use mone- of Monetary Shocks, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Work-
tary policy to stimulate the economy beyond full ing Paper No. 16-08, June 2016.
employment is likely to only increase inflation with 6
I n this context, linear implies symmetry.
no significant reduction in unemployment.
This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its
Regis Barnichon is a research advisor at the Federal entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the
Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Christian Matthes is Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the
a senior economist and Tim Sablik is an economics italicized statement below.
writer in the Research Department at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
Endnotes
of Richmond, the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
1
 onald P. Morgan, Asymmetric Effects of Monetary Policy,
D
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, Second
or the Federal Reserve System.
Quarter 1993, vol. 78, no. 2, pp. 2233.
2
For example, see James Peery Cover, Asymmetric Effects of
Positive and Negative Money-Supply Shocks, Quarterly Journal
of Economics, November 1992, vol. 107, no. 4, pp. 12611282;
and Emiliano Santoro, Ivan Petrella, Damjan Pfajfar, and Edo-
ardo Gaffeo, Loss Aversion and the Asymmetric Transmission
of Monetary Policy, Journal of Monetary Economics, November
2014, vol. 68, pp. 19-36. A working paper version is available
online.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK


OF RICHMOND
Richmond Baltimore Charlotte Page 4

También podría gustarte