Está en la página 1de 21

American Economic Association

Overlapping Generations: The First Jubilee


Author(s): Philippe Weil
Source: The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 22, No. 4 (Fall, 2008), pp. 115-134
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/27648280
Accessed: 07-02-2016 20:28 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of
Economic Perspectives.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

22, Number 4?Fall

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives?Volume

115-134

2008?Pages

Overlapping Generations:
The First Jubilee
Philippe Weil

Samuelson's

Paul

so

has

Seldom

(1958)

a model

simple

so

been

model

generations

overlapping

influential.

Its "wow"

feeling of surprise at its originality and coolness


The

years.

are

generations

of

spite

its

always

still

age,

ripe

the uncontroversial

from

Starting
new

in

paper,

elicits

coming

along"

turned 50.
and

factor,

the

have not paled with the

wonder.

observation

that

"we

in a world

live

unattributed

(all

has

where
to

refer

quotations

that violates the credo of the first


Samuelson,
1958), Samuelson built a model
fundamental welfare theorem with which we still inculcate undergraduates
50 years
later.

to Samuelson,

According

economies:

with

distortions

and

failures,

absent

competitive

the

in a framework

occurs

model

that

the

usual

not

is

theorem

usually

Mona

Like

Lisa's

popularity?along
I take

half-century.
of

exposition
tainty,

an

model

are,

with the many


it as my

of

of

economic
the

the welfare

why

to

in this

brief

results

the main

the

smile,

enigmatic

explanation

and

inwhich

proved.

generations

overlapping

Pareto

plausible

realistic than the world of agents living synchronous and finite existences
the

as

such
be

in an overlapping

more

ways,

of market

suspects

theorem

is, in many

best

need

equilibrium

of all, this failure of the firstwelfare

efficient. Worst
generations

even

in

well

necessarily

generations,

overlapping
market

is not

all

welfare

mysterious

extent,

significant

issues it has

celebratory

overlapping
properties

paper

the

the
its

in the last
after

provide,
model

generations
of

for

responsible

illuminated
to

of

properties

a short

under

cer

generations

overlapping

Philippe Weil isProfessor ofEconomics, Universit? Libre de Bruxelles (European Centrefor


Advanced Research inEconomics and Statistics), and at SciencesPo (Observatoirefran?ais des
conjonctures

?conomiques),

Paris,

France.

He

is also

Research

Fellow

of

the Centre

for

Economic Policy Research, London, United Kingdom, and Faculty Research Fellow, National
Bureau

of

Economic

Research,

Cambridge,

Massachusetts.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

116

model

so much

differ

in a deliberately

from

the

canonical
mode,

nonencyclopedic

of Samuelson's

Arrow-Debreu
a few

striking

to review,

and
and

applications

extensions

model.

straightforward

deceptively

framework

This paper is not the first attempt at an intellectual history of the overlapping
Solow (2006) sketches the main features of the model
in a
generations model.
volume

that

and

Samuelson

made

contributions

gathers

Economic

Modern

by

and

colleagues

at Samuelson's

friends

in 2005. Interestingly, Solow confesses that he forgot to


in his earlier 1983 book on Paul
generations model

90th birthday celebration


include the overlapping

Theory.

a wrhile

it took

Indeed,

for

Samuelson's

framework to impose itself on the profession. The Kareken and Wallace


(1980)
volume and Sargent (1987) textbook played a considerable role in itsdiffusion, and
(1987) and Farmer (1999, chap. 6) provide superb overviews of its
Geanakoplos
main

contributions.

The Model
In

this

time

as
be

My

wrong.)"

Solow

in an

goal,

features

of

version

from

of

to

notes,
a

produce

era when

the

the

"test

positive

rationale

generations

overlapping

own

Samuelson's

(2006)
to

needed

Samuelson's

rendering.

B?hm-Bawerk's
rate
for

of

that

idea

interest.

such

(It

objectives

thought, is instead to highlight what

to the history of economic


essential

streamlined

markedly

was,
would

preference
to be

present

differs

times

motivation

original
out

section,

that at

model

turned

belongs

I take to be the

the model.1

Birth and Death

Demography:

the world

Imagine

is

of a

comprised

succession

never-ending

of

generations.

The perpetual renewal of cohorts (or, under uncertainty, themere possibility that new
is a crucial element of the overlapping
cohorts might appear),
generations
model?I

arrival

The
tions model:
calls

return

will

this

biological

of

to

and

pop

up

accordingly

is only

interpretation

I discuss

is exogenous

cohorts

"birth"

when

point

generations

additional
process

this

an

welfare

issues.

in Samuelson's

spontaneously
refers

expositional

to

the

genera

overlapping

in the

economy.

"newborn."

convenience.

The

Tradition

However,
newborn

this
could

little green people deposited on our planet by storks or aliens, or


our shores. More
immigrants just disembarked on
radically, souls of all beings may

as well be

have

been

planted

in the economy,

spies,

since

time

immemorial

and

his early training in France tomention


here thatAllais
(1947)
in a 135-page
model
early version of the overlapping
generations
to his book. To explain wrhy it attracted little attention, Malinvaud
that it is
(1987) opines
appendix
of many cases and to introduction of long formulas." But ?
"rather complex,
leading to consideration
tout seigneur, tout honneur: credit must be given where it is due.
It behooves

developed

an economist

like dormant

what

amounts

who

received

to an

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

PhilippeWeil

be

could

out

gradually

coming

common

denominator

strated early on by Shell,


The

of

the

as

cold

active

economic

demon

(as

agents

117

1971).
of

these

is that

interpretations

matters

what

is

economic birth:deep down, a "new" agent is not defined by age, nor biological or
ethnic characteristics, but by the fact that it is not included in the economic
calculus
left

of

their

by

individuals.

to

parents

this vantage

for

fend

disowned

point,
or

themselves,

unloved

to whom

children

loved

contrast,

By

From

agents.

pre-existing

are

immigrants,
ascendants

generous

are

who

children

"new"

have

be

immigrants in a society in which they are cherished and


queathed wealth,
are
to old bloodlines,
to
not. They are best thought of as belonging
helped,
pre-existing

families

or

societies.

selves

are

severed

current

bind,

or

constitute

"new"

economic

disconnection
with

In combination

infinite

in

model
no

the

the

as

is ever

agent

of an

previous

model

generations

succession

unending

with

together
model.

workhorse

of

and
is about

generations,

of dated
in

contrast,

the

of

is

goods,

Ramsey-Cass

macroeconomic

dynamic

is part

rate

the arrival

the number

By
of

individual

every

in which

model

incarnations

cohorts.

theory),

pre-existing

One

family.

as a limiting case of the


overlapping

should therefore think of the Ramsey model


generations

constraints

borrowing

are comprised of "new" agents implies that the total

other

born:

their

overlapping

future

generations
the

when

radically,
from

the

assumption

agents,

overlapping
serves

(which
new

and

economic

of distinct

number

short,

current

that generations

the hypothesis

more

economically
In

individuals.2
of

Even

of

new

economically

has

agents

shrunk

to zero. I will return to this insight below.


Death
(alternatively: kidnapping by storks or aliens, or emigration) is certain.
It could be assumed to occur randomly, as when Blanchard
(1985) adopts Yaari's
(1965) simplifying assumption of age-independent death probabilities, or even with

zero probability, as in my model of overlapping


infinitely-lived families (Weil,
as
none
matters
the
of
the overlapping generations
this
of
1989);
specificity
really
model
on

than

economist
different,

exact

the

length

of

the

lives.

of

arrival

How

to understand

wants

who
of

on

qualitatively,

depends,

and

why

when

the

disconnected

new,

agents

consumers

overlapping

vanish

rather

is, for

the
is

model

generations

interest.

secondary

(1958) splits lives into three periods, but he also examines briefly
a version with two periods dubbed youth and old age. Most of the literature,
following the lead of Cass and Yaari (1966), has adopted the two-period normaliza
it has the technical advantage of wiping out intertemporal trade
tion because
Samuelson

between
ascendants
encounter

two

consecutive

only
rules

once:
out

cohorts.
when

intergenerational

When
am

there

young
exchange

(and

are

two
they

because

ages
are

of
old).

executing

I meet

life,
This
an

my

once-only
intertempo

2
Townsend

can be
(1990) pointed out that the overlapping
(1980) and Woodford
generations model
consumers
reinterpreted as a world of staggered binding borrowing constraints hitting infinitely-lived
the random dates at
In Aiyagari and McGrattan
(1998), the average time between
every other period.
of the endogenous
which the level of assets hits zero serves as a measure
average economic
lifespan.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

118

ral

trade

the

two-period

the number

models

to assume

to the one

Samuelson

and

economy

that
that

"chocolate"
on

exchange

it is

arbitrary

equilibria.
more

purposes:

number

of

by

or

periods,

in

receive,

and

are

date

given

that there is only one


nonstorable.
on

presumably

with

spot

at a

born

agents

identical.

stemming from the date of birth.

nonproduced

agents

the

all

assume

(1958),

others

lest

Samuelson

a hot

it melts.

Call

must

and

day,

and

el

in the

good
calls

this

the

good
or

eat

either

e2

in the first and second periods

received by agents

endowments

an

compute

for most

is immaterial

with

to

it easy

entailed

rather than discretely, yield similar insights although

limits heterogeneity

Following

itmakes

specified

trade

intergenerational

to handle.

harder

Technology

of

because

it is convenient

Finally,

This

absence

periods

generations

overlapping

are much

they

of

time flows continuously

which

The

is convenient

version

Fortunately,
realistic

twice.

meeting

requires

chocolate

of their life.

Preferences
To

to consider

enough

care

sumers

in which

infinitely

of

weights

the utility

impatience,

the

across

consumption

overlapping

("infinitely

reason

I do

why
who

only

versus

of youngconcavity

old-age

the

of

current

I abstract

to

with

the
the

these

details

relative

degree

of

to smooth

the desire

capturing

of
will

consumption

capturing

from

extreme

the

in between,

consumption

utility

However,

periods.

about

function

and

consumers"),

("almost infinitely impa

the way

somewhere

con

in which

patient

all

go

care

course

is of

Reality

not

it is

model,

generations
economies

preferences:

consumption

consumers

below.

and

polar

of

they mostly enjoy eating when young

impatient
clear

become

the

versions

old-age

The

consumers").

of

properties

two

about

only

economies
tient

the main

reveal

here.

Autarkic Equilibrium
The

foregoing
us

enable

tion)

there
so

are

that

assumed
exchange

right

that

away

and must feel happy about

equilibrium3
There

streamline

(which

assumptions
to conclude

are
two

four

periods

reasons
of

mtergenerational
away
either:

they (because

there

life, agents

should

belonging

exchange

within-cohort

say,

to lend

they are just like me),

be

any

trade

to different
as

impossible

heterogeneity,
I wish,

original

must

be

formula
in

self-sufficient

it.

cannot

is

Samuelson's

consumers

there
to members

and none

in

discussed

can

be
of my

Because

equilibrium.

cohorts

meet

only

no

mira

generational

generation,

of them would

once,

Because

above.

so would

borrow from me.

The recursive competitive


when
it is born solves its own
(in which each generation
equilibrium
interest rate) coincides under certainty with
problem given the then-prevailing
two-period maximization
theWalrasian
(in which the souls of all agents, born or unborn, meet at the
competitive equilibrium
are quoted a sequence of
their
beginning of time and
intertemporal prices under which they determine
a result, I will not distinguish between
the two concepts.
optimal behavior). As

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Overlapping Generations: The FirstJubilee

Because

the

is not

good

consumption

no

storable,

consumer

wants

to

119

choc

keep

olate in a pocket from young to old age (itwill melt away). Finally, if the economy
or the planet is closed to foreign trade (which I assume), there is no possibility for
interest

The
for

with

goods

exchanging

chocolate

might

reflects

(as

technology

summarized

are

consumers

whether

ensures

and

that

of

chocolate

clear.

the

or

that

desire

level

equilibrium

endowments

it is at this point

patient

the

Its

trades

today

eliminates

that markets

the value

by

infinitely

at which

mechanism

of the individuals)?and

the preferences

terms

the

is the market
to trade

have

extraterrestrials.

determines

which

rate,

tomorrow,

consumers

or

foreigners

el and

e2 and

that it starts to matter

impatient.

Iwill now show that the equilibrium interest rate is either very low or very high
to whether the
(below or above the rate of growth of population)
according
is

economy
the

case,

with

peopled

very

is not

equilibrium

competitive

or

patient

very

Pare

consumers.

impatient

In

to-optimal.

the

In

latter,

the

former

it is. The

very

fact that itmight not be iswhat elicits wonder: how can it be that the firstwelfare
theorem fails to hold when the interest rate is low?
Low

rate

interest

tions

models.

Samuelsonian

"Samuelsonian"

rate

young

receive

who

agents,

and

tastes,

but

don't

of a

requirements

and
from

-100

punitive
future

To
they

will

in both

endowments

try

to

the

exchange
some

extra

of

periods

the mismatch

mitigate

against

enjoy

what

and herein
equilibrium.

time

ex units

valuable

of

percent:

In
of

equilibrium?the
faced

our

this
the

with

infinitely

endowment

this

setting,

transfers from young

it is trivial

to old

terms

consumer
consumes

old

eY of

lies the symptom of the Pareto


In

net

equilibrium
extreme

patient
each

equilibrium,

chocolate

such

remember,

they get

when

old.

trade

e2 as
young?

this is one of the


current

between

to deviate

wish

required
It

rate must

interest

not

does

The

to execute

simply

in

autarky.

goes

to waste,

sub-optimality of the competitive

to construct

that improves

the

of

of

pattern

chocolate

goods

care

life, only
the

between

is that there is no one with whom

above,

competitive

chocolates,

autarky.4
But

as

spend more

exchange.

genera

"classical,"

latter.

For agents to be happy with this situation?and

called

I will

standard. Unsurprisingly,

difficulty,which we discussed

be

are

economies

Gale

by

fascinating features of overlapping

interest

the

consumption.

old-age

endowments

this

dubbed

Economies
our

Suppose

when

are

than

former

been

have

the most

high

properties

the

discussing

about

contrast,

By

their welfare

economies

they exhibit

(1973) because

sequence

of

intergenerational

the lot of every generation:

simply

rate of
the equilibrium
interest rate equals
the marginal
evaluated at the endowment
consumption
point, so that
second-period
+ v(c2). In the
I am discussing, the marginal
(eY) /v' (e2) if the utility function is u(cx)
example
is always nil?that
Hence
1 + r = 0, and r = ?100
is, u'{
) =0.
utility of first-period consumption
From microeconomic

substitution
1 + r= u

between

first principles,

first- and

percent.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

120

in

confiscate,

endowment
consume,

this

old,

source

rate

These

storage

off

set aside
rate

as

infinitely

could

it

for

equals

to old

more

Since

age.
to

possible
a

by

social

planner

t<

<
infinity,an amount r,with 0
get

for

something

do

young

store

the

exceeds
alternative
r is below

rate

interest
that

the

yields

a
to

been

no

tax when
resources

optimum

rate

of

would
rather
much
the

happen

to

storage
concomitant

that

Then,
r<n,

interest

transfer

out

that

gains

some

date

transfer

central

rate

until

old.

when

when

planner

of

population

as

long

younger

the
of

the
n

growth

provides

sequence

proposed

superior
rate

interest

transfers

from

itwill be more beneficial


than

generation

storage

in this

the

by

to

of

rate

the

and
old.

it would

to

have

is a welfare

young

from

private
reaches

capital
the

rate

interest

n, when

the whole

consider

generally,

situation

to old
and

rate

the

what

return to storage is decreasing,

competitive

young

as

long

is below
More

the marginal
from

as

setting,

technology

starting
the

the

economy.

is attained

in which

crowding
the

the

n. As

return

private

is transferred

young

in a world

constant.

than

product?until

the

the

n,

out

Crowding

is fixed by the linear production


endowment

As

Left to their own devices,

if the

of

the next

from

optimorum

use

will

aside.

goods

from

redistribution

rate

implicit

in a Samuelsonian

idea

improving
The

chocolate.

under

the young

with

but

improving. For each generation,


old

above,

chocolate

of

starting

young,

r. However,

rate

growth

when

transfer
store

larger

store

chocolate

storing

r, intergenerational

population

young to old is Pareto


receive

at

proliferate

r)el in the competitive equilibrium.

transferring,

surrender

chocolates

Chocolates

goods described

el units

put

one

that

equilibrium

and

0,

is better,

young, but they get them back with a vengeance.


can

each

1, from young to old. The old in the initial time

nothing:

generations

Subsequent

from

gains

the

is instead

r, so

The

r<

when

possibility:

and

(1 +

there

return

transformation).

consumption

is e2 +

of

instance,

Suppose

tomorrow.

of

new

extent

its fullest

growth

statements

the

every

net

exogenous

partially

one

have

consump

growth
of

the

consumption.
seem.

rate

melt

In

r chocolates

marginal

consumers

the

achieved

1 +

-1,

n +

they may
with

exogenous

and

than
a

population

most

then

is growing

guarantees

case

old-age

chocolates
into

here,

growth

old

numerous

exogenous

the

of young

If population

to the equilibrium with nonstorabie


old

until

of

than

(the
r ?

when

above,

compare

period

equal

in which

values

only

general

technology

be

number

times more

I consider

rate

result, their old-age consumption


Now

young

added,

the

mutates

impatient

storage

to

since

today

then

be

easily

technology

their mattress
the

1 +

from

e{,

to the old. The

an

thus

from

growth

apply

otherwise. Compared
our

are

the young
transfer

are more

results

self-destruct,

can

is better

generation

interest

that

economic

n would

about

chocolate

population

perpetual

of

at

linear

and

r <

<

transfer it lump-sum

(1 + n)T to each older person. Although

endowments

of

sequence

only

made

n, so

rate

tion of e2+
is the

t, with

e2 instead of e,2in the competitive allocation.

constant

the

and

a constant

assuming

amount

lump-sum

of the young

old, e2+ t >


at

perpetuity,

the
of

should

be

ensuing

growth

where

of

rise

there

is so

increased?with
in its
marginal

population.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

This

is

121

PhilippeWeil

Samuelson's

rate of interest" or Phelps's

"biological

"golden rule" of capital

(1961)

accumulation.
two

Notice

growth
the

rate

interest

of

because

the

ris

less

run

must

transfers

Pareto-improving

direction,

opposite

the

fails when

theorem

n. First,

Pareto-improving

intergenerational

I discuss below why, and not simply how, the

I will return when

transfers to which
first welfare

of

characteristics

essential

than

from

fundamental

rate

the

of

population

to old,

young
of

asymmetry

not

and

time:

in

is an

there

initial instant (the big bang, or today), but no last period. As a result, any transfer
from old to young, be it implemented in a low or in a high interest rate economy,
hurts the first generation of old that it affects. If Eve had been taxed when old to
of

from

If transfers

This

complain.

from

transfers
old

when

to old.

young

ceased

can

she would

Abel,

Second,

be

Thus,

generalized

eliminating

one

the

pattern

perpetual.

generation?the

gradual

of

regardless

be

when

anything
to

off

must

a while,

receive

worse

been

transfers

after

not

does

also

have

young-to-old

cold-turkey

but

young

argument

old?would
out

phasing

transfers

from

of
to

young

a Pareto-deterioration.^

involves

always

rate.

to old

young

is taxed

that

and

Cain

interest

the

of

the value

one

to young

transfers

provide

Economies

Classical

or

rate

interest

High

"classical"

are

economies

generations

overlapping

less

as I will show below,


interesting from the welfare point of view (even though,
of

usefulness

the

overlapping

that

Suppose
little

and

very

very

valuable,

about

care

their

the
are

wipe

the

This

growth
The

is enough
of

population
resulting

endowment
endowment

the more
to ensure
for

competitive

situation

to borrow.

inclination

consumers'

consumption,

old-age
rate.

out

in this

want

they
that

very

the

low

the

in

their

r<

the

n case).

utility

is

their

this

age
is not

second-period
as

autarkic,

(again,

The

to borrow

value

of
be

young

is a

discussed

requirement

interest rate must be very high

equilibrium

allocation

most

must

allocation

happy

to

consumption

old-age

against

then the equilibrium

for competitive equilibrium),


to

consumption
Since

to borrow

equilibrium

to be

about

consumption.
like

limited

features.

mainly

old-age

would

However,

If consumers

above.

consumers

the young

endowment.

generations

I will just sketch theirmain

Accordingly,

is not

model

of

peculiar:

less

that

and

the

interest

rate

agents
higher

the

is above

second-period
the

care

young

the

about
interest
rate

of

consumption.b
consume
their

in the first period ex,which they value, while the old consume their
e2,which they value very little.One might tempted to argue that it is

case: if the marginal


rate of return on
statements could be wrong in one semi-pathological
These
are old when the system is eliminated would
storage increased sharply with the amount stored. Those who
of its curtailment. The resulting
still be poorer, but they would have stored more goods in anticipation
fall
the detrimental
if it is large enough,
beneficial
increase in the return on storage could overcome,
in lifetime wealth. See Weil
(2002) for details.
6
interest rate goes
If the marginal
goes to zero, the equilibrium
consumption
utility of second-period
to infinity, since the equilibrium
interest rate 1 + r = u' (e^/v' (e2) tends to positive
infinity when
?/( ) is small and goes to zero.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

722

after

Pareto-suboptimal:

most of the chocolates


them

to

lump-sum
to

symmetrical
answer

is

the

the

it be

who

young

low

like

rate

interest

while

negative:

wouldn't

all,

if a

better

social

confiscated

planner

of the old, since they enjoy them so little, and redistributed


so much?

them

of

economy
who

generations

take

the

Isn't

part

exactly

subsection?

previous

in both

case

this

of

phases

The

the

old-to

young redistribution would obviously be better off (they are giving up chocolates
for which they have little appetite when old against chocolates which they crave
when young), the initial old (who are taxed in the second period without having
a

received
they

prevent

one.

Stalinist

ment

social

they

the

not

symmetry
the

interest

rate

economy.

the

and

not

would

of

last:

asymmetry

at a

The

Even

perfect

some

of

sense.

to

Pare

but
alive

currently

economy

to

old

case

would

be

also

imple

But

this

is

obviously

ruled

reestablished,
in

upon

of

(instead

young

I have

be

improved

to the initial old")

keep

always,

his

put

of an

existence

transfers

the

from

taxing the
case

nongeneric

is as extreme

as the

in a few words

finger

initial

. . Must
.

beginning

the Lord

Welfare

generations model,
is

and

as

concise

mankind

economies

generations

there

from

we

and

period

forever

births

the

give mankind

on

the
of a

absence

an

end

as well

so let us tackle one

rested after the beginning,


constant."

Properties

failure of the first welfare

The

the

to

enough

planner.

and

the

time

Strange

is

case) would be Pare to improving because

between

give

as a beginning?
problem

but

by much,

that

in

extreme

could

their welfare.

Stalinist

lucid

"We must

welfare

all?an
rate

allocation

("pay no attention

the

Samuelson,
crucial

and

the welfare

at

interest

Transfers

decrease

its implication

preferences

off

improve the lot of all generations

to sacrifice

low

competitive

young to old in the Samuelson


old

worse

not

chocolate,

improving

chocolates

enjoy

that

initial

from

ready

are

They

about

for the benefit of all future generations, would

with

sense

the

high

planner,

did

the

off.
little

transfers.

old

out?then

to young would

(the initial old)

old-to-young
If

care

redistribution

old-to-young

consumers

in

off because

transfers from old

Hence

are worse

in the first)

transfer

are worse

is

puzzling.

because

in low interest rate overlapping


would

Pangloss

like

the

overlapping

all seems to be for the best in this best of all worlds:


there

competition,

theorem

Voltaire's

are

no

externalities

no

and

distortions.

So what

is going on?
The Wrong Answer
Let us startwith a dead end. It is tempting to think that inefficiency stems from
the
I

argued

tions model
are

of

impossibility

already

at

conducting

the outset,
is

only

present

an
at

the

trade
generational

interpretation.
the

with

beginning

and

previous
interpretation

We
of

could
time,

and

as well
meet

future
of
have
at

generations.

the

genera

overlapping

assumed

that date

as

But,

that
to trade

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

all
as

souls
they

Overlapping Generations: The First Jubilee

in

wish

low interest rate economies.


of

trade

would

encounter

still

as we learn from Shell

Thus,

cannot

descendants

and

ascendants

with

we

markets:

Arrow-Debreu

complete

of

key

in

inefficiency

the impossibility

(1971)

the

be

123

the

explanation.

The Right Answer


us

Let

to a more

turn

subtle

but

germane

of the firstwelfare theorem fails in overlapping


let us

why,
one

proves

of

the world

leave
a

that

competitive

is

equilibrium

traditional

while

short

and

examine

in a

Pareto-optimal

proof

To understand

generations models.

for

Samuelson

The

argument.

static

how

exchange

economy.
that

Imagine
and

over,

to

compared
there

are

there

endowments

of,

the market
a

is not)

two
two

agents,

there

is

each

They
and

apples

of

fruits

have

preferences

oranges.
the

remember:

(and

reallocation

Pareto-improving

Paul.

goods,

perishable

outcome,

and

Jane

between

that,

Suppose

is to prove

point
and

Jane

Paul.

Say

IfJane is better
itmakes Jane strictlybetter off and leaves Paul's utility unchanged.
reallocation
of
fruits
must
the
because
be
it
off,
provides her with a
proposed
have

she would
at

the

of

her

utilitymore
and

Jane
value

of

(or more
gate

Paul
their

on

whose

is

had

more

spend

together

of

endowment

apples

on
and

of at

of that fruit. Hence


aggregate
is

least

one

supply

for

at

and
But

oranges.

fruits must

least

one

way

agents

good),

the

same

reallocation,
combined

and

two

goods

this implies that aggre

the aggregate

is infeasible
and

as

spends

the

than

two

with

and

the value

he

to obtain

oranges

exceed

reallocation

than

oranges

in the proposed

of agents and goods),

the

the proposed

apples

reallocation

unchanged,
a

been

(otherwise,

prices

proposed
and

apples

welfare

(if there

endowment

a finite number
generally

equilibrium

more

competitive

in the

Hence,

own).

spends

the

cheaply, Paul would have found it). Thus,

consumption

exceeds

at

afford

to Paul,

As

of his

value

the

her

Jane

prices,

endowment.

fruit

not

could

it on

selected

competitive

before

she

that

basket

consumption

as

endowment

(aggregate
a

result

demand

the market

Pareto-optimal.

this proof may break down. The key


In overlapping generations models,
is that with an infinite number of households and of dated goods?Shell's
(1971) double infinity?an allocation that is too expensive at market prices need not
be infeasible, so that the firstwelfare theorem need not hold. In a nutshell, if the
reason

value
is not

of

the

resources

necessarily

available

synonymous

to the economy
with

consuming

is infinite,
more

than

spending

more

on

goods

is available/

'
Here

of infinity. Index
of the strange mathematics
is, for the curious reader, a compact presentation
and endowments
of the fruits clhand eih,and
and Jane by h and fruits by i, call their consumption
measure
the price p? of the fruits in some num?raire. Wrhat we are saying is that a Pareto-improving
in the aggregate: E,,(2,-/>,- c/h)> 2/,(2,p? e?,?).
With two agents and two
reallocation must be too expensive
a finite number of agents and of goods), we can switch the two summation signs
goods (more generally
and 2^(2, p, ejh) =
on each side of this inequality. As a result, we can write 2/,(X,- p, cjh) = 2, p?C2,hO?
>
we
For
this
the
get ^?pj?Z,, c/h) JJjpj(JJ/!eih).
inequality to hold,
inequality,
ItjpjCZt, eih). Substituting into
we
Hence
i for which 2;, cih> E;, eih since prices are non-negative.
there must be at least one good
in a situation of "double
is infeasible. However,
reallocation
conclude
the proposed
infinity," the
Paul

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

124

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

The Gist of the Story


What do we learn from all this?
First,
resources

Samuelsonian

economies

are

different.

on

the

drastically
with

synonymous

"infeasible."

different

With

by

because

infinite
it is

Indeed,

allocation

competitive

are

economies

to

possible

infinite
is not

expensive"
in the Pareto

improve,

resources

redistributing

"too

resources,

with

from

young

sense,

to old

forever.

(1971) analogy with Gamow's


(1947) static room allocation problem
an
rooms
hotel with
infinite number of
is illuminating (the italics are mine):
Shell's

An

innkeeper has committed

beds

on

a certain

rainy

a bed can be found


bed.

In our

little

each of the denumerably

night.

guest

if the innkeeper

chocolate

of
but

occupied,

can

allocation

imposed

extra chocolate.

infinite number
all are

when

each guest tomove

requires

the

game,

for a bed

asks

in a

down one
one

produce

In the hotel problem, on the other hand, the


innkeeper by
an
will be able to produce a denumerable
allocation
imposing
infinityof extra

beds.

In a hotel with a finite number of rooms, it is not possible


without
market

someone

throwing

in the

and

street,

to produce

the first welfare

theorem

an extra bed
holds

absent

imperfections.
Samuelson's

Second,

in which

economies

stroke

of

the first welfare

was

genius
theorem

a model

to construct
holds,

always

absent

distortions, look like quite a special case. It ishard to escape


features

a world

overlapping
all, can we

after

exception:
against

the

of

the

where

seriously

of a model

realism
new

generations

that
are

are

model

generations
argue,
rests

once

entirely

always

coming

we

the

the
along?"

externalities

and

the conclusion
what

than

"new"
that

assumption
In

that the

rather

norm,

understand

on

that makes

that

the

means,

"we

live

in

it is not

respect,

the overlapping generations model, with the wealth of interesting issues it raises
and its rich welfare properties, that is a simple toymodel, but rather the competing
workhorse
assumes

of modern
that no

"new"

the

macroeconomics,
generation

ever

comes

Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans
as future
agents
along

model
are

all part

that
of

on debt
(1974)
pre-existing
neutrality and Weil
a
make
it
clear
that
such
model
if
(1987)
emerges only
parents love their children
to
future
leave
all
of
them positive bequests. This condi
(or
immigrants) enough
families. Barro's

famous paper

of the summation signs over households


and goods that we have performed might not be
that is
legitimate because of Fubini's theorem (Rudin, 1987, theorem 8.8), and as a result an allocation
too expensive
is not necessarily infeasible. This happens,
in particular, when the value of the aggregate
endowment 2^(2,p,
are dated
e/h) is infinite. If goods, as in the overlapping
generations model,
goods,
then i in fact indexes time. Normalizing
the initial price to 1, p1 is just the present value in the initial
+ r)-' if the interest rate is constant. As a result, the first welfare theorem
period of time i goods, or (1
fails to apply when r< 0, that is, in a Samuelsonian
economy with an interest rate below the (zero) rate
commutation

of population
Shell (1980)

growth. This argument was generalized


by Okuno
to economies with time-varying interest rates.

and Zilcha

(1981)

and Balasko

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

and

PhilippeWeil

tion

is very

rate

that

to

the

exceeds

always

overlapping

cure

To

the

that

in low

inefficiency

for

that

desire

literally

quite

interest

long-run

extraordinary

compared

interest

and

transfer

from

goods
interest

are market-based

there

to old

to old

youth

needs

that will reduce

the

that

it is

(remember

age

are

There

rate).

one

economies,

transfers from young

the

down

Samuelsonian

rate,

centralized

mechanisms

solutions.

Remedies

Centralized

most

The

to

drives

this,

doing

rate,

its

Inefficiency

consumers

of

is

with

model,

Ramsey

model.

a way to implement perpetual


desire

the

growth

generations

to Cure

How

therefore

and

restrictive,

125

obvious

is of course

way

to set

up

unfunded

pay-as-you-go,

straight

social security system that pays retirement benefits to the old from the taxes levied
on

their

young

perpetual,
of

collapse

will

population

of a pay-as-you-go

the

instance,

If n falls

by

rate

interest

grows fast (n >

system.

the

Pareto-improving,
for

n below

growth

deterioration. When
support

be

its elimination?motivated,

population

a democracy

To

contemporaries.

and

its elimination.

must

be

reversal
to a Pareto

lead

r), old and young are aligned

below

r, their

are

systems

Pay-as-you-go

system

unforeseen

r?will

interests

thus

in
in

and

diverge,

in an aging population,

it is likely that the old, whose weight is heavier

prevent

an

illustration

prime

of

the

difficulty of policy design in a democracy: the temptation to create them is large


(old and young will vote for them when growth rates are high) but once put in
are

they

place,

almost

of

economy

political

impossible

Another

social

security

are

who

of agents

tion,
labor

the

terminology7
out

crowds

ratio

and

raises

genera

overlapping

to think about the design and

systems.

of repaying national

debt

falls upon

to the
present

unconnected

(1965) who
public debt.

future generations

cohorts,

financing

public

debt raises the net wealth of the currently alive agents

deficits by issuing national


and

Samuelson's

inwhich

remedy is, following the work of Diamond


this approach into the overlapping generations model,

If part of the burden

(to use

out.

phase

centralized

first introduced

comprised

to

model
is thus, very naturally, the

tionsmodel

of Barro's

private

capital

the

interest

1974

seminal

rate.

increases

paper),

accumulation.

This

lowers

from

Starting

an

the

their

consump

long-run

capital

that, without

economy

public debt or unfunded social security, has an interest rate below the growth rate,
issuing public debt will be beneficial to all. In point of fact, from a normative
viewpoint, public debt should be increased up to the golden rule?the
optimum
optimorum

above

described

constant

without

level

ever

where

the

of

public

levying any

debt

taxes

interest

rate

equals

(if it spends nothing)

the government

At that point,

per

capita

to finance

from

one

the debt.

the

growth

rate.

can in effect roll over


generation

How

to

the

next

is this possible?

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

126

the

Suppose

borrows

government

b>

constant

0 from

each

cohort

young

and

(1 + r)b to each old. Since the young are 1 + n times more numerous
than the old in a growing economy, the system finances itselfwithout injection of
tax revenue provided that (1 + f)b ? (1 4- n)b?that
is, ifwe are at the golden rule

thus owes

where

n. Note

a world,

in such

that

the

has

government

freed

itself

to a Ponzi

equivalent

sense

in the financial
of future

a chain

scheme,

is

what

precisely

enables

and

game,

pyramid

(the value of the debt exceeds

This

surpluses).

or

letter,

itsdebt is

it is insolvent

the present discounted


to cure

the government

the

from

intertemporal budget constraint that ties down the actions of individuals:

value

through

a dose of public debt the inefficiency intrinsic to low interest rate economies.
The overlapping generations model disciplines the mind into realizing that
unfunded social security and public debt operate in a similar fashion. Indeed, it is
to be

inconsistent

logically

debt?unless,

public

are

redistribution
enous

labor

in

favor

of course,

on

to bear

brought

of

other

the

than

against
wealth

intergenerational

as moral

such

analysis,

and

security

or

hazard

endog

supply.

Cures

Decentralized
Samuelson

originally

the

proposed

"social

contrivance

inefficiency of low interest rate economies.


useless

intrinsically

prints

social

pay-as-you-go

considerations

of

"oblongs

of

Suppose
into

paper"

to cure

money"

the

the initial old generation


or

greenbacks

unusable

stamp

"circles of shells" that they offer in exchange for chocolates to the initial young. Will
the young accept paying a positive price for an intrinsically useless asset? The

answer is both no and yes: no, if they do not expect to be able to resell it later; yes,
if they do and can pass it on like a hot potato for a positive price to the next
In other

generation.

one

young,

multiple
at

closely
useless

that when

observe

words,

look more

us

Let

generation

Samuelsonian

money

note

as

In other

this

of

the money

is the only

it is

words,

If the

young

at

time

of

price

can

way money

role

an

is a

"money"
or

only

store

pure

t each

must

goods)
yield

buy

the

mt goods

to the

unfunded

social
with

currency

very

itdoes not facilitate

so

it cannot

and

interest,

of value,

worth

at

appreciate

rate

of return

in

offered

hyperinflation

that

can

its return

of risk, the real price ofmoney

thus

same

First,

them

(the sellers). Hence


as

of the word:

dividend

come solely from a capital gain. In the absence


inverse

same

the

no

it pays

goods

sell
are

that

to the old

(the buyers)
plays

the old

price,
the

result,

is valued.

money

as Reichmarks were during the German

even be used as a wallpaper


1920s.

positive

Samuelsonian

that

to barter,

compared

to the usual meaning

limited attributes compared


transactions

Samuelsonian

As

it is valued

when

Second,

system.

security

the

other.

circulate from the young

payment

of

the

when
have

greenbacks

after

exist.

equilibria
case

the

as

the

rate

of

nonmonetary

of Samuelsonian

money,

(the

interest:
assets.
the

real

value of themoney that they hold, and that theywill sell to the young born at t+ 1,
will thus increase to (1 + r)mt by the time they retire. Now what the old will sell, the
young

must

buy.

clearing requires

Since

there

that (1 +

are

r)mt

at any

time

1 +

young

for each

old

alive,

(1 + n)mi+l.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

market

Overlapping Generations: The First Jubilee

This
high

balances

us

helps

equation
rate

interest

understand

mt would

to

explode

Samuelsonian

why

Were

economies.

Samuelsonian

money
is inconsistent

infinity?which

with

real

a useless

of

price

asset

to grow

has

at

1 +

rate

r. If the

in

place

r>

when

since the resources of the young who buy it are limited at el. The
the

no

has

money
valued

127

real

n,

market-clearing

intuition is that
n at which

speed

buyers of this asset (the young) enter the economy falls short of the speed rat which
the

there

world,

we
supply.8 If

to economize,
uelsonian
mean

still be

would
say,

money
by

return

(1 4- n)mt+l

that

that
m =

the

room

for a

out

to low

interest

or

r>

by

will

fall

eventually

trading frictions in Samuelson's


that

currency
time.

shopping
not

n, but

asset

useless

fully-fledged

costs

transaction

is ruled

the

introduced

the

consumers

enables

The

existence

existence

of
we

of what

Sam

usually

"money."
us

Let

on

for

demand

aggregate

appreciates,

price

short of the aggregate

golden

e{. The

then

young

of

purchase

current

relates
rule

Samuelsonian

n can

rate

economies

and

future

be

devote

their

all

n. We

constant

balances

unwanted

old

the

r) mt

conclude
at

the

optimum

level
to

endowment

first-period
when

(1 +

expression
to rand

balances
real

consume

and

money

real
with

reached

to the

and

the

optimorum

+
+
+
+
golden rule level e2 (1 r)m? e2 (1 n)ex. This allocation is the same as the one
that would be reached by optimal social security transfers from young to old or by
issuing the right amount of public debt without levying taxes. In fact, the level of
that

debt

public

Samuelsonian
Like

redistribution

ment

from

the

young

to old

of

the

of

case

in the

long-lived

on

the use

informal

of.
social

. .

as a

greenbacks

contracts,

like

contract:
of

that does not default on itsobligations

consensus

low

and

system
social

rule,

golden

inefficiency

security

it is part

because

to

economy

cure
social

pay-as-you-go

"works"

money

can

money
a

the

brings

social

m.

b, equals

interest

rate

public

debt,

perpetual
security,

In

short,

economies.9
Samuelsonian

intergenerational
a

govern

long-lived

in the case of public debt, or "a grand


money

institutions,

of
and

The

exchange."
common

values

message
are

that

of utmost

importance for economic outcomes (Caillaud and Cohen, 2000) is not the least of
the lessons taught by the overlapping generations model. Like formal laws, they are

assets?a

characterization

I borrow

from

Kotlikoff,

Persson,

and

Svensson

(1988)?

thatmay be vital to reaching efficiency.

8
to be complete, we should also note that if r is larger than n in the absence of
For the reasoning
itwill be even higher when it is present and valued. The reason is buying money
Samuelsonian
money,
towards old-age and that an increased
when young and selling itwhen old involves shifting consumption
interest rate provides the incentive to do so.
9
in which Samuelsonian
I have mentioned
here that there exists an equilibrium
the station?r)7 equilibrium with valued currency. There
and I have described

is not valued,
money
is also a continuum
of

indexed by initial per capita real balances, which can be anything between 0
nonstationary
equilibria
real balances
that converge to zero and interest rates that
and m. All these equilibria feature declining
should not conclude, as
money. One
collapse back towards the value that prevails absent Samuelsonian

occurs because
the autarkic steady state is Pareto-suboptimal.
The
long thought, that indeterminacy
in an economy with strong income effects that there is no such
work of Grandmont
(1985) establishes
was

causality.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

128

is another,

There

equivalent

rational asset bubble


greenbacks

useless.

intrinsically
in a

situation

analyzed

rate

interest

useless

intrinsically
exceeds

price

Samuelsonian

as

money

economies.

(r <

economies

the present

we

are

value

of

is valued,

currency

discounted

is, there is an asset bubble. Tir?le


for the existence of asset bubbles

generations

overlapping

asset

Rational

n) where

zero

(1985) has
in general

bubbles

of new

generations

ipso facto
the

occur

only

arrive

buyers

fast

in the economy. This result should not be a surprise: I am willing to pay for

enough
an

its real

where

equilibrium
in low

an

When

that it generates?that
exhaustively conditions

dividends

of

interpretation

that is relevant to the theory of finance. I have pointed out the


or stamped shells circulating in the
overlapping generations world are

more

asset

its fundamental

than

value

(the

discounted

present

value

of

future

dividends) only if I can sell it later to others. A rational asset bubble, like Samuel
I find someone to
sonian money, is a hot potato that I only hold for a while?until
it. The

catch

of new

arrival

consumers

the

generates

constant

flowr of new

to keep asset bubbles

partici

and similar chain letters going. The age-old


pants required
me
one
dollar in return for this postcard and send a similar
postcard game ("send
one dollar to 1 + r of your friends") is feasible and can go on
postcard requesting

forever if and only if its expansion rate r falls short of the arrival rate n of new
it
top of that, it is welfare-improving when feasible because
participants. On
then-needed

the

implements

of

transfers

logical corollary of the statement "models


are

holds
are

very

is thus:

extraordinary"

"economies

new

from

goods

inwhich

to old

participants.

the firstwelfare theorem always


asset

where

are

bubbles

never

possible

special."

Oversaving

Beyond

I earlier compared the overlapping generations model to theMona Lisa. One


feature of da Vinci's painting is thatMona Lisa's smile is seen differ

well-known

it seems to conveys depends on the


ently by each viewer, and that the meaning
position of the watcher. Similarly, each extension of the overlapping generations
reveals

approach

of

versatility

another

the

aspect

overlapping

of Samuelson's

generations

model.

model.

There

four

pick

examples

of course,

are,

many

of

the

more.

Intergenerational Risk Sharing


as Samuelson
I have so far proceeded
Disregarding

between

comparison
Samuelsonian
sense
many
interest
then,
postpone

of

and

classical
In

simplicity.

rates

did in 1958, ignoring uncertainty.


and dangerous.
It is convenient because the
rates
interest and growth
yields a sharp delineation of the

risk is both convenient

of

rates,
to assess

return:
like

the
on

growth

public
rates,

empirically

the answer

it is

cases;

real world,

to this

debt,

there
on

fluctuate

whether
question

however,

dangerous,

an

is

and

uncertainty,

capital,
over
economy

to the next

and
time

because

so on.
and

To

across

it

there

to address

how
or

are

matters,

aggravate
events:

is Samuelsonian
subsection

us a false

gives

as a result

are

we,

classical?

first a further

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

129

PhilippeWeil

more

and

serious

cannot

take

when

complication:

before

part

there

is

birth

their

in

the

uncertainty,

competitive

is never optimal because

generations model

librium of the overlapping

trades

risk-sharing

with

previous

This difficulty is specific to uncertainty and to insurance markets.


under

equi

the unborn
generations.

It does not arise

certainty.

is going on, imagine, for specificity, a version of the


overlapping generations model inwhich the splitof the constant aggregate endow
ment between young and old is random and decided by nature a minute before the
To

are

young

what

understand

born

and

to old

turns

youth

The

age.

are

young

too

born

they are

to share with their elders the risk to which

to be

late

Given

able

that only the

exposed.
split is random, young and old could pool their resources and avoid uncertainty
altogether if only they could meet before the realization of uncertainty. This
even with
is enough,
incomplete market participation
sequentially complete
Arrow-Debreu

to

markets,
outcome

This

in

stands

the

prevent

faultless

contrast

sharp

of

operation

with

the

the

invisible

case

certainty

hand.
as

where,

Shell

(1971) showed, it is immaterial whether or not the souls of the yet unborn meet at
the beginning of time. Under uncertainty, as pointed out by Chattopadhyay and
Gottardi
(1999), "we cannot find a sequential structure of markets where agents
trade only after they are born and which

as when
date."

agents
a

As

even

result,

absent

supports the same equilibrium

access

unrestricted

have

to a

complete

traditional

any

set of markets

market

failure

as

such

allocations

at

the

initial

distortionary

taxes, the equilibrium allocation of an overlapping generations model will always be


to be Pareto suboptimal:
left to their own devices, markets will not
expected

on

for)

But

are

is no

if there
under

"classical"

or

oversaving

oversaving

even

on whether

depend

is

there

out

crowd

not

does

whether

generations.

this Pareto-suboptimality

Remarkably,
it calls

across

risk

allocate

properly

not.

of course

can fill in for incomplete

therefore

welfare.

improve

in an

well-designed

scheme

vast

of

or

economy

there

is

that we

papers

to

that

uncertainty.
would

dub

redistribution

in insurance markets
strives

classical,

to old

young

intergenerational

participation
array

from

or not

whether

(for example,
a

transfers

Perpetual

intervention

is Samuelsonian

economy

beneficial,

oversaving

certainty),

(and the corrective public


the

characterize

and

can

optimal

social security schemes under uncertainty. A good starting point isBall and Mankiw
(2007), who offer an elegant characterization of the policies required to reach the
optimal

allocation.

This

discussion

shows that a distinction must

inefficiency (oversaving) and Pareto-suboptimality.


dynamically inefficient (or overaccumulates
capital)
not

reduce

increases

aggregate
it

in

some.10

consumption
Pareto-optimality

in

any
is a

future

be drawn between

dynamic
economy with capital is
if reducing capital today does

An

date

stronger,

or

event,

and

welfare-based,

10
The

actually
efficiency

literature on dynamic inefficiency dates back at least toMalinvaud


(1953). A criterion using bond
was developed
to
under
Cass
for
(1972) and generalized
inefficiency
certainty
detecting
prices
by
(1990, 1991).
uncertainty by Zilcha

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

130

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

that

criterion

requires

but also

possible,

not

the

only

of aggregate

"cake"

that it be optimally

as

be

consumption

agents. Hence
dynamic
the cake is not as big as it can

(because
inefficiency implies Pareto-suboptimality
be), but dynamic efficiency does not in general entail Pareto-efficiency.
under

certainty

the

uncertainty,
all

policies

failure

thus

in that

distortions):

to allocate

risks

efficient

dynamically

or

in Samuelsonian

needed,

Samuelsonian

case,

But under

across

properly

ones,

It does

economies

inefficient and Pareto-suboptimal.

of markets
even

allocations,

are

no

are both dynamically

with capital
renders

are

(if there

as

large

across

allocated

generations
Public

Pareto-suboptimal.

in classical

to achieve

economies,

the

optimal intergenerational risk sharing thatwould be reached under a Rawlsian veil


of ignorance. In Blanchard and Weil
(1991), my coauthor and I have studied the
existence and beneficial welfare properties of asset pricing bubbles in stochastic
shows

the

that

case

for

that

economies.

are

The

is not

overlapping

to use to think about social security?whether

model

real-world

efficient.

dynamically

transfers

intergenerational

to Samuelsonian

risk

economies

generations

overlapping

limited

This

argument

in the presence
is a

model

generations

or not dynamic

good

inefficiency is

problem.11

Inefficiency a Real-World Problem?


In a celebrated paper, Abel, Mankiw, Summers, and Zeckhauser

Is Dynamic
tigate

of

whether

empirically

actual

are

economies

(1989)

inves

Their

inter

efficient.

dynamically

rogation is essential because it could be that the exotic phenomena brought to light
(to name but a few: oversaving leading to a
by the overlapping generations model
low

interest

rate;

Pareto-improving

of

crowding-out

private

accumulation

capital

by

pay-as-you-go
security; public debt being beneficially transformed into a
asset
Ponzi game;
bubbles) are only theoretical possibilities that can happily be
shelved, after looking at the data, in the library of impractical and useless theories.
social

task

The
above,

the

set

authors
of

the presence

for

risk makes

is not

themselves
it

an

easy

to talk about

impossible

one

as noted

because,

"the"

rate.

interest

To

circumvent the difficulty of finding out which interest rate to consider and to skirt
the added complication stemming from the variation of interest and growth rates
over

time

and

events,

the

authors

devise

a clever

cash-flow-based

efficiency

crite

rion. Building on results by Phelps (1961), they show that an economy is "dynam
ically efficient" (I will explain the quotation marks in a short while) if and only if
goods

are

investors.12

always
Measuring

(at

every

date,

the direction

in every

state

of cash

of nature)

flows

from

flowing
national

out

of firms

income

to

accounts,

11
that have nothing to do with
There are aspects of social security programs
generations:
overlapping
for instance, the inability to make
time-consistent plans for the future and to adequately
provide for
the overlapping generations model
one's own retirement. Hence,
is certainly not the onlymodel of social
security.
12
The rationale

for this criterion is clear in steady state under certainty with constant population
growth
total return to capital is rK,where K is the aggregate capital stock, wrhile the investment
at the same rate as population
is nK. If the former exceeds
required to keep the capital stock growing
is classical.
the latter, then r> n and the economy

at rate n. The

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Overlapping Generations: The First Jubilee

that dynamic inefficiency does not seem to be a problem


in the 1925-1985
period or for the United Kingdom,
and
Japan between 1960 and 1984.
Italy, Canada,

they conclude
United
States
Germany,

must

results

These

be

care

with

interpreted

for

reasons.

three

131

for the
France,

the authors

First,

refer to dynamic inefficiency, but what they characterize is really Pareto-optimality,


as evidenced by the utility-based efficiency criterion that they provide.
Second, Abel, Mankiw, Summers, and Zeckhauser
(1989, p. 11) themselves
note

their

that

conclusion

empirical

that

real-world

are

economies

(Pareto)

efficient is valid only "if the economy behaves in the future as it has in the past."
and Kaul
Barbie, Hagedorn,
(2004) point out that the empirical implementa
et
al.
Abel
tion of the
criterion, which requires veri
(1989) Pareto-optimality
flow out

fying that goods


impossible:

to investors

of firms

statistical

conventional

can

methods

in every possible

is

future,

statements

make

about

what

"almost surely" (that is, with probability 1), but they cannot assert
will happen
sure
for
what will happen. For instance, flipping only heads in an infinite series
of tosses of a fair coin is very unlikely (it will almost surely not happen),
but it
is not

than

future

about

assumptions

used

those

to Zilcha

over

efficient

ically

paths

the

data

are

that

and

Summers,

1890-1999.

Kaul

weaker

under

conclude,
more

and

Zeckhauser

that the United

(1991),

period

and

Hagedorn,

the

of

Mankiw,

by Abel,

retical results due


be

Barbie,

Fortunately,

impossible.

plausible

and

States economy

is dynam
cannot

however,

Pareto-optimality,

theo

using

established.

we

inefficient,
librium

absent
the

what
state

any

would

of all

can

that

are

transfer

return

marginal

that

mechanism.

in a Lockean

to

out

crowd

below

the

growth

is, before
have

generations

is

The

been

In an

would

decreasing,
in

saving

rate?

that

asking

it exhibit oversaving?

capital

private

equi

in effect

of nature,"

across

goods

is dynamically

competitive

are

We

"state

physical

in a

reach

low interest rates?Would

the mechanisms

rates

interest

economy

like

an economy

would

transfer

that

it have

the

where

absence

the

look

institutions

market

economy

state

the

intergenerational

economy

and

to

refer

put in place. Would

in

we declare

third difficulty is subtle. When

The

physical

twentieth

the

assets

result

century

data

(1989) or Barbie, Hage


by Abel, Mankiw, Summers, and Zeckhauser
us about this fictitious
to
if
have
tell
and Kaul
little,
(2004)
anything,

examined

dorn,
reference point. During
used

to finance

many

Western

two world

wars,
and

countries,

unfunded

social

and

diamonds

gold

priced far above their fundamental


the many

given
current
private
the
out

ways

private

questions

capital

absence,
raised

of

seems

such

policies,

by

it would

Samuelson's

devised
no

to be
data

The

accumulation.
whether

value. What
have

societies

accumulation.

elimination

in their

our

there

generations,
capital

they examine, public debt was abundantly

the time period

as

do

not

pay-as-you-go

We

just
become

model

do

not

a host

and

were

to transfer
further

resources

rationale
on

provide,

assets

social
know

security,
how

from
for

their

own,
that

the economy
or

remain

in

deployed

of other

the data do tell us, however,

Samuelsonian
remain

systems

security

support
already
would
classical.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

is that
to

future

crowding

relevant.

were

out
for
crowd
look
The

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

132

Economies

Keynesian

The

occur

can

that

in one-good

in the overlapping

and

As

process.

steers

the

that

sentence

the idea of generations


economic

of

inefficiency

possible

tomorrow,

happens

to anchor

way

selection device

used

this
and

expectations,

This

statics

ties down

thatmolds

equilibria.

to the one

identical

what

terminal condition

comparative

animal

is, for

spirits
the

instance,

(1986).

It is quite

in terms

of

IS-LM
to

by Samuelson

revealing
diagrams,
introduce

"Our point of view is that for some purposes

(p. 755):

as

described

is better

activity

its

almost

on

and Polemarchakis

conducts

which

no

inefficient

from

away

of Geanakoplos

this paper,

starts with

government

economy

explicit message

the

depends

becomes

turns into an equilibrium

public policy
and

today

happens

generations model,

the

result,

and

environments, turned in the 1980s into the


of the attempt to give solid microeconomic
foundations to

What

economics.

economies

exchange

in undistorted

competitive equilibria
theoretical playground
Keynesian

with the indeterminacy of equilibrium

generations model,

overlapping

without

process

end."

are

We

all,

indeed,

children.

Paul's

Finance

Behavioral

a key role in the development


overlapping generations model has played
of behavioral finance. In one of the founding papers of this literature, DeLong,
Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann
(1990) introduce overlapping generations of
The

traders

noise

Summers,
the

in
tain

1990). Two

is no

the

of

result

striking

there

coexist

who

even

of

rational

traders

characteristics of the overlapping


that

that paper

fundamental

noise
on

uncertainty
model

generations

overlapping

cohorts

with

dividends.

that

risk.

Second,

and

Shleifer

generations model
affect

durably

asset

of a last

can

prices

the

of

ability

drive

even

prices

the absence

First,

ensures

of fundamental

in the absence

traders

also

(see

remain

when
period
uncer
to

arbitrageurs

revert to the mean is curtailed by factors


buy low and wait to sell high until prices
or
that
limit
their
economic horizons. The shorter the
institutional)
(biological
further

horizon,

the

presence

of noise

asset

traders.

prices
These

from

diverge
mechanisms

do

their
not

fundamental
rely

on

dynamic

values

in

the

inefficiency.

Conclusion

Einstein
General

(1924)

Theory,

of

the

reminded us, in the introduction


physicist

Ludwig

Boltzmann's

to Relativity: The Special and

warning

that

"matters

of

ele

gance ought to be left to the tailor and to the cobbler." Although aesthetic pleasure
is indeed not the metric of scientific achievement, the beauty radiating from the
striking simplicity the overlapping generations model has played a significant role
impact. What

in the paper's

verbatim

to

the

overlapping

Sassoon

generations

(2001) wrote about Mona

Lisa applies almost

model:

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Philippe Weil

of

[M]any

those

standing

before

the Mona

or other

Lisa

famous

133

are

artefacts

left a little disconcerted.

By the cultural conventions of the twentieth century,


nor
she is neither beautiful,
sexy. The painting is not grandiose, or politically
Delacroix's
Libert?
like
is no gore, no
inspiring,
guidant le peuple. There
It does

violence.

Solow
until,

not

(2006) marveled
at

the

least,

very

/ thankMicael

tell a

story.

Just

at Samuelson's
the next

woman,

plain

"innocent

smiling

little device."

little.

So should we all

jubilee.

Castanheira, Fr?d?ricMalherbe, Etienne Wasmer, and the editorsfor their

comments.

References

H.

Abel, Andrew, N. Gregory Mankiw, Lawrence


and Richard J. Zeckhauser.
1989.
Summers,

and
Dynamic
Efficiency:
Theory
Review ofEconomic Studies, 56: 1-20.
S. Rao,
and Ellen R. McGrattan.
Aiyagari,
1998. "The Optimum Quantity of Debt." fournal

"Assessing
Evidence."

447-69.
ofMonetary Economics, 42(3):
1947. Economie et Int?r?t. Paris:
Allais, Maurice.
Imprimerie

Nationale.

and Karl Shell.


1980. "The
Yves,
Balasko,
I: The Case
Model,
Overlapping-Generations
of Pure Exchange
without Money."
Journal of
Economic Theory, 23(3):
281-306.
and N. Gregory Mankiw.
2007.
Ball, Laurence,
Risk Sharing in the Spirit of
"Intergenerational
to
and Rawls, with Applications
Arrow, Debreu,
Social Security Design." Journal ofPolitical Econ
omy, 4(115):

523-47.

and Ashok
Barbie, Martin, Marcus Hagedorn,
Kaul.
Tests of Effi
2004. "Assessing Aggregate
for Dynamic
Economies."
in
ciency
Topics
Macroeconomics,
4(1).
1974. "Are Government
Barro, Robert.
Net Wealth?"

Brown, E. Cary, and Robert


Paul
Samuelson
and Modern

Journal ofPolitical Economy, 81(6):

Solow.

1983.

Economie

Theory.

McGraw-Hill.

and Daniel
Cohen.
2000.
Caillaud,
Bernard,
Transfers
and
Common
"Intergenerational
in a Society." European Economie Reviexv,
Values
1091-1103.
44(4-6):
1972. "On Capital Overaccumu
Cass, David.
lation in the Aggregative Neoclassical
Model
of

Economic

Growth:

A Complete
Characteriza
ofEconomic Theory, 4(2): 200-223.
E. Yaari.
1966. "A
Cass, David, and Menahem
of the Pure Consumption
Re-examination
Loans
tion." Journal

Model."

Journal

67.
Chattopadhyay,
1999. "Stochastic

ofPolitical Economy, 74(4):

353

Subir, and Piero Gottardi.


OLG Models,
Market
Struc

ture, and Optimality."


21-67.

Journal ofEconomic Theory,

89(1):

DeLong,
rence H.
1990.

Bonds

M.

Andrei
J. Bradford,
and Robert

Summers,
"Noise Trader

Risk

Shleifer, Law
J. Waldmann.

in Financial

Markets."

703-738.
ofPolitical Economy, 98(4):
Peter.
1965. "National Debt
Diamond,

Journal

in a

1095-1117.

Neoclassical

Olivier
Blanchard,
J. 1985. "Debt, Deficits,
and Finite Horizons."
Journal ofPolitical Economy,
223-47.
93(2):

1126-50.
Review, 55(5):
1924. Relativity: The Special
Einstein, Albert.
and General Theory. Methuen
and Co Ltd.

Blanchard,
1991. "Debt

Olivier
Ponzi

Jean,
Games

ciency under Uncertainty."


nomics, 1 (2): 5-27.

and Philippe Weil.


and Dynamic
Effi
Advances

inMacroeco

Growth Model."

American Economic

Farmer, Roger E. A. 1999. Macroeconomics


of
Self-fulfilling Prophecies. 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Gale,

David.

1973.

"Pure Exchange

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Equilib

Journal ofEconomie Perspectives

134

Models."
rium of Dynamic Economic
Journal of
Economic Theory, 6(1):
12-36.
1947. One Txvo Three . . . In
Gamow, George.
of Science. New York,

finity: Tacts and Speculations


NY: Viking Press.

Geanakoplos,
John. 1987. "The Overlapping
of General
In
Model
Generations
Equilibrium."
The New Palgrave Dictionary ofMoney and Finance,
vol.

1, ed. Peter Newman,


767-79.

John Eatwell,
Geanakoplos,
lemarchakis.

Murray Milgate,
Palgrave Macmillan.

and

M. Po
John D., and Herakles
1986.
"Walrasian
Indeterminacy

Review
and Keynesian
Macroeconomics."
of
Economic Studies, 53(5):
755?79.
1985. "On Endoge
Grandmont,
Jean-Michel.
nous Competitive Business Cycles." Econometrica,
995-1045.

53(5):

1980. Models

and Neil Wallace.

Kareken,John,
ofMonetary Economies. Minneapolis,
Bank of Minneapolis.
Rese?e
Kotlikoff, Lawrence J., Torsten
Lars

E. O.

Svensson.

1988.

MN:

Federal

and
Persson,
"Laws as Assets: A

to the Time

Prob
Consistency
lem." American Economic Review, 78(4):
662-77.
Edmond.
1953. "Capital Accumu
Malinvaud,
Solution

Possible

lation

and

Efficient Allocation

of Resources."

233-68.
Econometrica, 21(2):
Edmond.
1987. "The Overlapping
Malinvaud,
in 1947." Journal ofEconomic
Generations
Model
Literature, 25(1):

103-105.

and Itzhak Zilcha.


Okuno, Masahiro,
of Competitive
Proof of the Existence

1981. "A
Equilib

in a Generation-Overlapping
Exchange
with Money."
International Economic
Economy
Review, 22(1): 239-52.

rium

Phelps,
mulation:

E.

1961.

"The Golden

Fable

for Growthmen."

Rule

of Accu
American

Economic Review, 51(4):


638-43.
1987. Real and Complex Analysis.
Rudin, Walter.
New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
Paul A.
1958. "An Exact Con
Samuelson,
of Interest With or With
Model
sumption-Loan
out the Social Contrivance
of Money." Journal of
Political Economy, 66(6): 467-82.
J. 1987. Dynamic Macroeco
Sargent, Thomas
nomic Theory. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard Univer
sity Press.
Sassoon,

Donald.

2001.

"Mona

Lisa: The

Best

Known Girl in the Whole Wide World." History


1-18.
Workshop Journal, 2001(51):
of
Shell, Karl. 1971. "Notes on the Economics
Infinity. "Journal ofPolitical Economy, 79(5) : 1002
1011.
Shleifer, Andrei, and Lawrence H. Summers.
1990. "The Noise Trader Approach
to Finance."
19-33.
Journal ofEconomic Perspectives, 4(2):

Gener
Solow, Robert M. 2006. "Overlapping
ations." In Samuelsonian Economics and theTwenty

First Century, ed. Michael


Szenberg, Lall Ramrat
35-41.
tan, and Aron A. Gottesman,
Oxford,
UK: Oxford University Press.
and Over
Jean. 1985. "Asset Bubbles
Generations."
1497
"
Econometrica,
53(6):
lapping
1528.
Tir?le,

Robert.
1980. "Models of Money
Townsend,
with Spatially Separated
In Models
Agents."
of
and Neil
ed.
Kareken
Economies,
Monetary
John
MN: Federal Re
WTallace, 265-304, Minneapolis,
serve Bank

of Minneapolis.
1987. "Love Thy Children:
Weil,
Philippe.
on the Barro Debt
Reflections
Neutrality Theo
rem." Journal ofMonetary Economics,

19(3):

377

91.

Weil,

1989. "Overlapping
Families of
ofPublic Econom

Philippe.

Infinitely-Lived Agents." Journal


183-98.
ics, 38(2):

"The Transition
from
2002.
Weil,
Philippe.
to Fully
Social Secu
Pay-As-You-Go
Capitalized
In Institu
rity is Not As Painful as You Think."
tional and Financial

Incentives for Social Insurance,


Victor A. Ginsburgh,
d'Aspremont,
and Frans Spinnewyn,
191-99.
Sneessens,

ed. Claude
Henri

Dordrecht,
Publishers.

The

Netherlands:

Kluwer Academic

as
Michael.
1990. "Public Debt
Woodford,
Private Liquidity."
American Economic Reviezv,
382-8.
80(2):
E. 1965. "Uncertain Lifetime,
Yaari, Menahem
Life Insurance,
and the Theory
of the Con
sumer." Review ofEconomic Studies, 32(2):
137-50.

in
Zilcha, Itzhak. 1990. "Dynamic Efficiency
Models
Generations
with Stochas
Overlapping
tic Production." Journal ofEconomic Theory, 52(2):
364-379.
Itzhak.
1991.
Effi
Zilcha,
"Characterizing
Generations
ciency in Stochastic Overlapping
Models." Journal ofEconomic Theory, 55(1):
1-16.

This content downloaded from 189.125.96.10 on Sun, 07 Feb 2016 20:28:03 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

También podría gustarte