Está en la página 1de 18

Critical Public Health,Vol. 10, No.

2, 2000

Social capital and the third way in public health


CARLES MUNTANER* JOHN LYNCH & GEORGE DAVEY SMITH
*Department of Behavioural and Community Health, School of Nursing, and Department of Epidemiology and Preventive Medicine, School of Medicine, University of MarylandBaltimore The Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan Department of Social Medicine, University of Bristol

A BSTRACT The construct of social capital has recently captured the interest of researchers in social epidemiology and public health. We review current hypotheses on the social capital and health link, and examine the empirical evidence available as well as its implications for health policy. With regard to theory, we contend that the construct as currently employed in the public health literature, lacks depth compared to its uses in social science. In addition, social capital presents itself as an alternative to materialist structural inequalities (class, gender and race) by bringing to the forefront of social epidemiology an appealing common sense idealist social psychology to which everyone can relate (e.g., good relations with your community are good for your health). The use of social capital invokes a romanticized view of communities without social con ict (e.g., Neo Tocquevillian nineteenth century associationalism) and favours an idealist psychology over a psychology connected to both material resources and social structure. We argue that the evidence on social capital as a determinant of better health is still scant or ambiguous depending on the definition that is used. Even if con rmed, social capital hypotheses call for social determinants beyond the proximal realm of social psychology. We also maintain that social capital is used in public health as an alternative to both state-centred economic redistribution (e.g., living wage, full employment, and universal health insurance) and party politics (e.g., gaining control of the executive branch of the government). Social capital represents a privatization of both economics and politics. Such uses of social capital mirror recent Third Way policies in Germany, UK and US. If Third Way policies end up losing support in Europe, its prominence there might be short lived. In the USA, where the working class is less likely to in uence social policy, interest in social capital could be longer lived or, alternatively, could drift in the academic limbo like other psychosocial constructs which at one point were heralded as the next big idea .

Within the last few years, we have witnessed the rapid appearance of the concept of social capital in public health discourse. Before 1995, there was only one reference to the term social capital in the Medline database and that was in regard to so-called
Correspondence to: Carles Muntaner, Room 655c, UMB, 655 West Lombard Street, Baltimore, MD 21201-1579, USA. Tel: +1 (410) 706 0889; Fax: +1 (410) 706 0253; e-mail: Muntaner@son. umaryland.edu
Critical Public Health ISSN 0958-1596 print/ISSN 1469-3682 online 2000 Taylor & Francis Ltd http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals

108 C. Muntaner et al.


family social capital and its effect on educational and occupational aspirations

(Marjoribanks, 1991). Though the basic ideas encapsulated in the current use of social capital can be traced to the origins of classical sociology and political science, the appearance of the term itself in the mid 1990s was largely stimulated by Robert Putnam s work on civic participation and its effect on local governance (Putnam et al., 1993). He popularized this thesis by discussing the decline of social capital using the metaphor that America was Bowling alone (Putnam, 1995a) a powerful image that propelled Putnam to an audience with President Clinton to discuss the fraying of the social fabric in America. Since then, the concept of social capital has also appeared in other fields such as sociology (Portes, 1998) and development economics (Grootaert, 1997; Ostrom, 1999). In these elds, there has been a good deal of debate about the definition, operationalization, and the theoretical and practical utility of the concept for improving human welfare, especially in regard to alleviating poverty and stimulating economic growth in less industrialized countries (Collier, 1998; Knack & Keefer, 1997). In fact, the World Bank sponsors a website devoted exclusively to the topic of social capital, where information is exchanged and issues actively debated. Despite all this activity, one of the leading scholars in this eld, Michael Woolcock, has argued that the concept of social capital . . . risks trying to explain too much with too little (Woolcock, 1998, p. 155). He says that the term social capital is being . . . adopted indiscriminately, adapted uncritically, and applied imprecisely (Woolcock, 1998, p. 196). Social capital and its use in public health We believe Woolcocks critique is especially true for many of the ways that the term social capital has been used in relation to health. To date there has been very little systematic theoretical, empirical, or practical appraisal of the concept in the public health literature, although more critical accounts are beginning to appear. (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a; Muntaner et al., 1999; Lynch et al., 2000; Hayes & Dunn, 2000 unpublished observations; Hawe & Shiell, 2000). Nevertheless, the term has slipped effortlessly into the public health lexicon as if there was a clear, shared understanding of its meaning and its relevance for improving public health. The term social capital and its close cousin, social cohesion, have been used as multi-purpose descriptors for all types and levels of connections among individuals, within families, friendship networks, businesses and communities (Wilkinson, 1996; Aneshensel & Sucoff, 1996; Kawachi & Kennedy, 1997; Kawachi et al., 1997a, b; Fullilove, 1998; Baum, 1997, 1999; Kennedy et al., 1999). In addition, it has been the subject of theme conferences (11th National Health Promotion Conference, Perth, Australia) and government sponsored discussion papers (Jenson, 1998; Lavis & Stoddart, 1999); it has been the topic of million dollar calls for research proposals funded by the Centers for Disease Control in the US, and on the basis of highly dubious comparisons between observational studies and clinical trials of such things as anti-thrombolytic therapy, it has even been proposed as an important avenue of public health intervention. Lomas has argued that interventions to increase social

Social capital and the third way in public health 109 support and/or social cohesion in a community are at least as worthy of exploration as improved access or routine medical care. Certainly they are more worthwhile than public healths traditional risk factor modi cation approach to cardiovascular disease (Lomas, 1998, p. 1184). These are impressive, yet completely untested claims. Similarly, in a recent book, published by the Health Education Authority in Britain, the authors state that, There is a consensus in recent literature that the construct of social capital may be usefully applied to the study of health and health-related behavior. (Cooper et al., 1999, p. 4). They leave the impression that we know much more about the theoretical and practical value of social capital than an examination of the actual evidence would suggest. Furthermore, they go on to say that, Researchers have measured social capital in terms of the social, collective, economic, and cultural resources available to a family, neighbourhood or community. (Cooper et al., 1999, p. 4). There are a myriad of indicators of social, collective, economic and cultural resources across the levels of families, neighbourhoods and communities are they all markers of levels of social capital? We are not concerned about the multi-dimensionality of the concept, but we are concerned that this multi-dimensionality has received so little theoretical exploration in regard to public health. Consequently it provides little guidance about the importance of the particular mechanisms that might link these different dimensions to health. Stated in this undifferentiated way, the laundry list of measurement strategies outlined above merely suggests that there may be a little something for everyone in social capital. Hawe & Shiell (2000) have commented that the health-related applications of social capital have often involved measuring all that is good in a community. Con ating the political, cultural and economic aspects of a community under the one umbrella of social capital, may mask important conceptual distinctions as to the origins of those group resources and may obscure the fact that these dimensions are not necessarily equally important as determinants of health. It would seem that under this kind of undifferentiated approach to social capital, establishing an arts festival (the cultural dimension) and a job creation program (the economic dimension) are both interventions to improve social capital are they likely to have an equal impact on public health? This in no way denies the importance of improving the cultural life of a community through programmes of arts and music. The question is whether tossing all these dimensions into the grab bag of social capital can inform strategies to improve public health. The reasons for the easy and almost completely uncritical acceptance of social capital into public health discourse is of interest in itself. Discussion of the concept would appear to come from at least three main sources within the public health community from those concerned with community-based health promotion (Baum, 1999; Cooper et al., 1999); from those in the social support eld (Cooper et al., 1999;Tijhuis et al., 1995), and from those who have claimed that social capital and social cohesion are the main mediators of the link between income inequality and population health (Wilkinson, 1996; Kawachi et al., 1997a, b). One factor that perhaps links these diverse areas of public health research and practice is that they are all motivated to some extent, by the underlying idea that there is something

110 C. Muntaner et al. about the connections among individuals that is important for public health. Levels of population health may be more than the arithmetic sum of the health of the individuals in those populations, and the determinants of population health are both individual and contextual. In this view there is something inherently social about improving public health that cannot be reduced to studying and changing discrete individuals. This idea is not new (Rose, 1985) and there have been many critiques of an overly individualistic approach to public health research and intervention (Krieger, 1994; Lynch et al., 1997; Muntaner & OCampo, 1993).The concept and language of social capital has perhaps been seen as offering a new and exciting way to invigorate supra-individual public health research and to provide support for a non-individualized, social science approach to improving public health (Baum, 1999). Public health and the connections among individuals The goal of moving beyond individualistic theory and practice in public health is laudable and as one of us has recently argued, the connections among individuals are an important and neglected research area in epidemiology and public health. In that paper, Koopman & Lynch (1999) showed how the different arrangement of connections among individuals can produce very different patterns of infectious disease transmission in a population. Infectious disease transmission depends on who is connected to whom, and it is possible that other disease processes are also in uenced by the pattern of connections within a population. This disease transmission perspective perhaps provides another language for understanding how social support has sometimes been found to protect against certain poor health outcomes. High levels of social support block the transmission of the pathogenic agent, in this case, usually hypothesized as stress. Populations are not just unrelated heaps of individuals, whose patterns of connections can be ignored. However, overly simplistic interpretations of the pattern of connections among people may mask, not reveal determinants of population health. For example, strong links among individuals can both increase and decrease the risk of certain health outcomes.Tight connections among infants in a day-care centre may increase their risk of otitis-media. In one context, strong friendship networks of peers can increase the risk of smoking, drinking or use of illicit drugs, while in a different situation these same sorts of links may decrease the risk of suicide. Tight networks among the Ma a, neo-Nazi parties, or semi-clandestine business organizations such as the Trilateral Commission, the WTO or GATT increase health risks for other members of the population. Scratch beyond a super cial level and the public health consequences of how individuals and groups are connected rapidly becomes very complicated. As we have stated above, we are advocates of the idea that the way individuals and groups get connected to form friendship networks, neighbourhoods, communities and populations can be important for public health. However, we are less convinced that the concept of social capital, in its present form, can provide an

Social capital and the third way in public health 111 adequate basis to understand how these connections may be linked to population health. We believe that social capital has been under-theorized in its public health usage, and that it is time to engage in serious debate about its de nition, measurement, and application in public health research and practice. It is within this broader framework of appreciating how both the formal and informal connections among individuals, and the connections among population sub-groups are linked to population health, that we must critically evaluate the concept of social capital.We think that some of the issues for public health research and practice are 1) to explore the sources of the connections among different individuals and groups i.e., what determines who gets connected to whom? 2) to understand what is transmitted over those networks that might be plausibly linked to health outcomes; and 3) to understand how the health relevant aspects of the connections among individuals and groups can be changed to improve public health. Theoretical differences with social science
When I use a word, Humpty Dumpty said, in a rather scornful tone, it means just what I choose it to mean neither more nor less. The question is, said Alice, whether you can make words mean so many different things. The question is, said Humpty Dumpty, which is to be the master that s all. (Lewis Carrolls Alice Through

the Looking Glass). Because the scant empirical literature on social capital and health has been accompanied by enthusiastic expectations about social capitals future relevance to public health (Kawachi et al., 1997a, b; Marmot, 1998; Mustard, 1996), social capital often conveys the authoritarian arbitrariness of Alices famous exchange with Humpty Dumpty. Powerful institutions, actors and funding agencies have a lot to say about what a concept means and what concepts are considered legitimate for empirical research (Muntaner et al., 1997; Muntaner, 1999a, b;Wing, 1998). Nevertheless, because public health is a science, and thus has adjacent disciplines, we can examine the compatibility of its social capital construct with regard to the social capital theories that have been developed in contiguous disciplines (e.g., sociology, demography, and international development). Almost exclusively, the construct of social capital adopted by public health researchers has been the most psychological, the communitarian view (Putnam et al., 1993). This conception emphasizes civic engagement, as in membership in local non-governmental organizations, or norms of reciprocity and trust among community members. Communitarians, who often favour minimal government and self-reliance (Etzioni & George, 1999), present their position as a third way between laissez-faire neoliberalism and social democracy (Etzioni & George, 1999), and have been supported by the New Labour and New Democrat administrations in the UK and USA (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a). The small government communitarian view, with its emphasis on civic organizations (third sector, not for profit institutions, and Non-Governmental Organizations), not only undermines government intervention in the social democratic European welfare state; but also undermines political representation,

112 C. Muntaner et al. since national class-based parties that strive for state control are substituted with idealized notions of small scale political organizing at the community level (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a).Thus, it is possible that in public health, social capital may function as a health policy alternative to large scale government redistribution (i.e., dismantling or reducing the post-World War 2 welfare state) (Wainwright, 1996; Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a). In social epidemiology more speci cally, social capital presents a model of the social determinants of health that does not include any analysis of structural inequalities (e.g., class, gender or racial relations) in favour of a horizontal view of social relations based on distributive inequalities in income (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999b). As a consequence, class, race or gender-based political movements are also ignored as explanations for reducing social inequalities in health (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a). In spite of the confusion regarding the referents of social capital (Coleman, 1990; Woolcock, 1998), there is no justi cation as to why public health scholars should restrict their conception of social capital to the communitarian notion of civic participation and its indicators (e.g., organization membership, newspaper readership). In social science, in particular in sociology, demography, and developmental economics, social capital has at least two other conceptualizations that have a larger sociological content: one is that of network analysis (Granovetter, 1973; Portes, 1998; Woolcock, 1998). This view of social capital derives from the Weberian tradition in sociology and acknowledges the existence of strati cation as well as the negative effects of strong networks for communities (e.g., in Ma a families). For example, Granovetter showed the differences in the networks of professionals and non-professionals weak ties among professionals facilitate access to information about job opportunities. Portes showed the conditions under which strong networks among immigrants have facilitated the enrichment of ethnic businessmen in the US. Another sociological approach to social capital emphasizes the role of institutions, including the state. Following the seminal work of Evans (1995) on economic development, this institutional approach considers both a communities social capital its internal cohesion, ties and networks as well as the type of relation that the state has with communities (Szreter, 1999).This embeddedness or institutional support dictates how the state co-operates with civil society to foster economic development via interaction between private and public institutions, legal and democratic systems, and citizen rights (Woolcock, 1998). As we will show below, and have argued earlier (Lynch et al., 1999), this notion of social capital is the more encompassing and allows the greater explanatory potential and integration with other sociological traditions in social epidemiology and public health (e.g., the study of the health effects of class, gender and race relations). Idealist social psychology Bowling with de Tocquevilleand other exaggerations Social capital in public health is coined in terms of a lay/common sense social psychology that has great appeal in the US and elsewhere (Cooper et al., 1999; Baum, 1998; Kawachi et al., 1997b). Who would oppose the notion that civic

Social capital and the third way in public health 113 participation, trust in communities, good neighbourly relations are good for health? In the US, the mom and apple pie idea that good community relations are desirable is part of the collective wisdom among communitarians, liberals and social conservatives alike (Putnam, 1995a, b; Etzioni & George, 1999). Behind this conventional aspiration for achieving healthy communities also lies an idealized view of past community life that is seldom-warranted (Lynch & Kaplan, 1997). A particular form of historical imprecision is the selective reading of Alexis de Tocqueville, a French aristocrat, known for his observations on the high degree of civic participation in American communities during his nineteenth century journey in the US (e.g., Kawachi et al., 1997a,b; Kawachi & Berkman, 2000). Leaving aside the contradictions in Democracy in America (Elster, 1993), de Tocqueville displayed a sharp critical view, for example, when re ecting on the individualism and self-suf ciency that is so dear to communitarians: Individualism is a calm and considered feeling which disposes each citizen to isolate himself from the mass of his fellows and withdraw into the circle of family and friends; with this little society formed to his taste and leaves the greater society to look after himself (de Tocqueville, 1835/1969). This sentence highlights the perils of narrow associationism, or a negative effect of social capital which is largely absent from current public health and social policy writings on the subject (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a). A negative appraisal of vibrant, local associationism in the US is not new, however. Multiple local interest group associations are part of American Exceptionalism (Muntaner, 1999a) and these strongly localized associations may be seen as both potential barriers and supports to creating public policies aimed to improve population health. For example, the failure of creating a broad working class political party capable of establishing a strong welfare state, including the lack of universal access to health care (Navarro, 1994), has been a barrier to improvements in public health in the US. Furthermore, a recent analysis of voter participation data in American cities circa 1880 lends no support to the social capital perspective whereby civic associations would have beneficial impact on broadbased political participation (Kaufman, 1999). Rather, these analyses reveal that civic associations functioned as powerful interest groups that lobbied for speci c party platforms that were not necessarily in the broader public interest (Kaufman, 1999). Another inaccuracy of the received wisdom in current public health accounts of social capital is the uncritical acceptance of Putnams Bowling alone thesis on the decline of social capital in the US (Kawachi et al., 1997a; Kawachi & Kennedy, 1997; Kawachi et al., 1999;Wilkinson et al., 1998a, b).The available evidence in the US suggests that there has not been a decline in associations over the last two decades (Smith, 1997; Paxton, 1999). Furthermore, older forms of civic participation that have perhaps declined have been transformed over time (Fukuyama, 1999; Skocpol, 1999). In addition, Putnam s analysis of social capital as the key factor underlying economic development in several Italian regions (e.g., EmiliaRomagna) has also been challenged (e.g., the neglect of class relations or 19th century socialist and catholic political traditions in the creation of contemporary social capital; Warren, 1994). The notion that social capital drives political and

114 C. Muntaner et al. economic performance has been refuted with new analyses of data from Italian regions and other industrial democracies (Jackman et al., 1996). Our overall point here is that the discourse around social capital in public health has tended to focus on its upside. We believe a more complete reading of the literature relevant to understanding the likely health effects of social capital reveals that the concept has been portrayed narrowly and has focused on more optimistic appraisals of its relevance to population health. Communitarians of the world unite! Ignoring the class, gender and race structure Given the scant support for the social capital hypotheses reviewed above, one would expect that policy makers and researchers alike would be more sanguine in their approach to the subject. At least, some acknowledgement of alternative mechanisms driving the political, economic and health performance of nations (e.g., political movements, and class relations) might be expected from objective scholars. Unfortunately, in the enthusiastic entourage of social capital, this is not the case (e.g., Kawachi et al., 1997a).The eld is indeed inundated with paradoxes and omissions. For example, although communitarians such as Vaclav Havel accept the end of the nation-state (Havel, 1999), that is, of its welfare policies (universal health care, public education, subsidized housing, poverty relief, unemployment compensation, etc.), they are often accepting of international military interventions under the umbrella of powerful nation states (e.g., NATO s war in the former Yugoslavia; Chomsky, 1999a). Even the most erudite scholars seem to dismiss competing alternatives to social capital. For example, in the elds of comparative political sociology and economic development, dependency and world-system theories are far from exhausted, contrary to what Woolcock claims in his exhaustive review and integration of social capital studies (Woolcock, 1998). The early Dependency (e.g., Andre GunderFrank, Fernando-Henrique Cardoso) and world-system theories (e.g., Immanuel Wallerstein, Christopher Chase-Dunn), which were a spin-off of the Marxian tradition in sociology, have de facto evolved into stronger research programs that retain some of their ideas. This has happened for several reasons, including, 1) in recent years there has been a number of empirical articles on these theories in the leading sociological journals (American Journal of Sociology, American Sociological Review); 2) hypotheses arising from these theories of development (e.g., that receiving aid from the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank is associated with increased income inequality) have been con rmed by researchers coming from different perspectives (e.g., Boswell, who comes from the Marxian tradition, and Nielsen, who does not; see Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a); and 3) controversies in this eld have reached such a degree of sophistication that the issue is less whether IMF or WB aid is associated with increases in a nations income inequality (it is), but rather the timing of these income inequalities (Dixon & Boswell, 1996; Kentor, 1998; Alderson & Nielsen, 1999). In other areas of social science,

Social capital and the third way in public health 115 social capital has been integrated with research on social inequalities (e.g., class, gender and race). For example, in historical sociology, Gould explains social class mobilization in the Paris Commune with network analysis and pre-existing levels of social cohesion (Gould, 1991, 1993). Another area of integration between stratication and social capital is the sociology of gender. Brines (1999) for example, has shown how earnings equality among cohabiting couples reinforces cohesion and stability, making couples more likely to remain together than in conditions where one of the members of the couple (most notably the woman in heterosexual couples) earns more than her male partner. In addition to class and gender (Erikson, 1996; Muntaner et al., 1999; Persell et al., 1992; Zweigenhaft, 1993), racial and ethnic segregation has also been linked to social capital (Borjas, 1992). Contrary to the law and order view of social capital often portrayed in public health, Pattillo (1998) has showed the difficulty of separating networks of law abiding and criminal residents in cohesive African American neighbourhoods characterized by dense networks. Recently, researchers have also found that educational networks (Colemans original notion of social capital) are class and racially segregated (Schneider et al., 1997). Thus, in social science the elds of class, gender and race/ethnic inequalities are often integrated with social capital (mostly its network and institutional versions). However, with few exceptions (Matthews et al., 1999) the mostly communitarian approach to social capital in public health shies away from these mechanisms (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a, 1999b). Familiar health policy implications The importance of subjectivity One implication of social capital in public health is the role of individual subjectivity in mediating the relation between inequality and health (Wilkinson, 1996, 1999). The breakdown in social cohesion occurs because individuals perceive their relative position in the social distribution of income, which creates anxiety and other psychosocial injuries which, in turn, affect health (Wilkinson, 1999). As no explanations for the causes of income inequalities are provided, this psychosocial mechanism becomes the central explanation of social cohesion models in public health (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999b; Lynch et al., 1999). This is not surprising as individuals look for explanations and they hold to those that are offered (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999b). The move towards psychosocial explanations on the effects of social cohesion (e.g., the culture of inequality; Wilkinson, 1996, 1999) is rather surprising, as just a few years ago the eld of social inequalities in health was still materialist (Kaplan, 1995). Even researchers that had been relatively sympathetic to materialist explanations such as social class and working conditions (Marmot & Theorell, 1988), seem suddenly convinced by social capital/psychosocial environment explanations for health inequalities (Marmot, 1998). The culture of inequality mechanism underlying the social capital health association is not, however, all that innovative. For example, the culture of poverty hypothesis popularized by Oscar Lewis (1998/1963) is strikingly similar to the social capital/social cohesion formulations by Wilkinson and colleagues, albeit more

116 C. Muntaner et al. psychologically reductionist and victim blaming than the latter (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a).The culture of poverty states that some poor communities bring poverty onto themselves because of few community ties and little community heritage (i.e., social capital). Perceptions and subjectivity are all important, as it is not objective inequalities that ultimately determine the well being of populations but the subjective response to those inequalities. One of the implications of the social capital/social cohesion hypothesis for public health is that communities may be seen as responsible for their crime rates (Sampson et al., 1997) or aggregated health rates, an idea that nicely justifies the privatization of health services, such as managed care (Stoto, 1999). Another possible direction for public health may be that we take a step back from the structural sources of health inequalities (the importance of subjectivity,Wilkinson, 1999) after all, if they are not an integral part of our theories of health inequalities and are so dif cult to change, then perhaps an achievable alternative is to retreat to mass psychotherapy for the poor to change their perceptions of place in the social hierarchy (e.g., Proudfoot & Guest, 1997). Again, this idea is not new. In the 1960s the functionalist sociologist Warner revealed his hopes for his book called Social Class in America The lives of many are destroyed because they do not understand the workings of social class. It is the hope of the authors that this book will provide a corrective instrument which will permit men and women better to evaluate their social situations and thereby better adapt themselves to social reality and t their dreams and aspirations to what is possible. (Warner, 1960, p. 5). Elsewhere, we have labelled this new set of public health implications associated with the idea of a loss of social capital blaming the community (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a).The problem with subjectivity as an explanation for health inequalities is not only that it has little empirical support but also that it may yield anti-egalitarian public health policies (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a, 1999b). Such anti-egalitarian public policy outcomes are not desired by any of the proponents of the social capital/psychosocial environment approach to health inequalities, or for that matter, anyone in the broader public health community. This is because social egalitarianism constitutes one of public healths core values (Muntaner, 2000). The perceptions of relative inequality approach implies a psychophysical dualism that is at odds with scientific psychology since Sechenov and Pavlov (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a).The culture of inequality view implies that culture is non-material (a subjective invention of peoples minds that is not tied to the material world), while economics is material (Wilkinson, 1999). There is no basis for this assumption in modern science: ideology, technology, and art are as material as political representation or production of goods and services.The process of writing an article on anarchism is a cultural activity, selling it is an economic activity and censoring it because of its content is a political activity all of them material processes, as they take part in a social system, which is a material, albeit not physical, system (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a).

Social capital and the third way in public health 117 Can social capital be saved from shallowness? Why now? Explaining the growing interest in social capital The literature on different approaches to social capital (e.g., communitarian, network, institutional) has been growing for the last three decades, from Loury, Bourdieu and Coleman, to Portes, Evans and Putnam (Coleman, 1990; Putnam, 1995b). However, not until the 1990s has the concept of social capital/social cohesion gained popularity in public health (e.g.,Wilkinson, 1996) and development studies (Woolcock, 1998). To understand the timely emergence of social capital from a psychosocial construct in the sociology of education (Coleman, 1990) to the next research paradigm in developmental economics at the World Bank (Stiglitz, 1996, 1997), we need to understand the dif cult position of international lending institutions in the current decade. After the demise of the Soviet Union, the so-called Washington Consensus rhetoric of minimal governments, austerity measures, debt repayment, and neo-classical (e.g., rational choice) economics pervaded unchallenged (Chomsky, 1999b). Maybe the clearest example of this attitude is the now famous 1991 Memorandum attributed to Lant Pritchett and Larry Summers, currently US Secretary of Treasury and then chief economist at the World Bank. This unique historical document provides a testimony of the policies of the Banks ideology that has been replaced by the language of social capital at the end of the decade (e.g, Stiglitz, 1996,1997;Woolcock, 1998). Following Summers:
Dirty Industries: Just between you and me, shouldnt the World Bank be

encouraging MORE migration of the dirty industries to the LDCs (Less Developed Countries)? I can think of three reasons: 1) The measurements of the costs of health impairing pollution depends on the foregone earnings from increased morbidity and mortality. From this point of view a given amount of health impairing pollution should be done in the country with the lowest cost, which will be the country with the lowest wages. I think the economic logic behind dumping a load of toxic waste in the lowest wage country is impeccable and we should face up to that. 2) The costs of pollution are likely to be non-linear as the initial increments of pollution probably have very low cost. Ive always thought that under populated countries in Africa are vastly UNDER-polluted, their air quality is probably vastly inef ciently low compared to Los Angeles or Mexico City. Only the lamentable facts that so much pollution is generated by non-tradable industries (transport, electrical generation) and that the unit transport costs of solid waste are so high prevent world welfare enhancing trade in air pollution and waste. 3) The demand for a clean environment for aesthetic and health reasons is likely to have very high income elasticity. The concern over an agent that causes a one in a million change in the odds of prostate cancer is obviously going to be much higher in a country where people survive to get prostate cancer than in a country where under 5

118 C. Muntaner et al. mortality is 200 per thousand. Also, much of the concern over industrial atmosphere discharge is about visibility impairing particulates. These discharges may have very little direct health impact. Clearly trade in goods that embody aesthetic pollution concerns could be welfare enhancing. While production is mobile the consumption of pretty air is a non-tradable. The problem with the arguments against all of these proposals for more pollution in LDCs (intrinsic rights to certain goods, moral reasons, social concerns, lack of adequate markets, etc.) could be turned around and used more or less effectively against every Bank proposal for liberalization. (Summers, as cited in Valette, 1999) This economic logic that if applied to interpersonal, rather than international relations, would be considered psychopathic, had to change once a series of economic crises in part fuelled by IMF and WB policies started to creep up around the globe (e.g., Mexico, Russia, Brazil, and East Asia; Galbraith, 1999). Criticism of IMF austerity policies escalated (Kolko, 1999) even at WB headquarters where the Bank s new chief economist began using a more social democratic language where a positive role for governments was acknowledged, including references to social capital as a key factor in economic development (Stiglitz, 1996, 1997). The Banks interest in social capital thus marked a departure from economic imperialism, rational choice and public choice models, and a growing attention to integrating economics with sociology (Woolcock, 1998; World Bank, 1999a). Recent annual reports from the Bank also include the social dimension of economic development, including the need for government intervention in reducing international inequalities in science and technology (Stiglitz, 1997;World Bank, 1999b). Sceptical observers argue that economic development happens precisely when countries do not follow IMF policies (Chomsky, 1999b); that countries that receive IMF and WB suffer increases in social inequalities (Kentor, 1998); and that social democracy has already been successfully tested in some European countries during part of the World War 2 period, without need for social capital explanations. On close scrutiny, now that communism and big bureaucratic states cannot be blamed, social capital allows for a different kind of criticism of debtor countries (e.g.,Woolcock, 1998). Social capital allows for the characterization of countries as corrupt or developmental according to the character of the ties between state, private sector, and civil society (Evans, 1995). For example, after the crisis of 1997, South Korea, a country formerly praised for its Asian values and Confucian capitalism, became an example of crony capitalism, while the role of the deregulation of Korean nancial markets in the crisis was ignored (Galbraith, 1999). In the case of Russia, the economic policy dictated by Harvard and the IMF (Wedel, 1998) are not to blame for its failure to develop, it is Russian corruption (The Economist, 1999).Thus, in the WBs post-Washington Consensus documents, the interpretation of what happened to Russia in the 1990s is thought of as capitalism without proper social capital (i.e., de cient governmental regulation), rather than communisms inevitable heritage (World Bank, 1999a, b). Russian events such as the 30% GDP decline and unregulated monopolies are explained as the outcome

Social capital and the third way in public health 119 of a deliberate hurry to privatize before any institutional capability to regulate could be put in place. Russian events are used as an example of social capital failure that provides a rationale for the Banks retreat from neo-liberalism and its attempt to build a new development theory. Social capital is used to inform a supposedly new comprehensive and participatory approach to development, which avoids small government and authoritarian top-down neo-liberalism (Stiglitz, 1997; Woolcock, 1998). The underlying notion is that with adequate levels of social capital (proper civil and state guidance and regulation), the internationalization of markets and private property are optimal for the welfare of nations (World Bank, 1999a,b). Social capital thus represents a leaner version of previous proposals on various degrees of state intervention in capitalist economies. There is thus a correspondence between the WBs approach to social capital and its public health applications (less state interventions, emphasis on civic life, blaming the community, sharing responsibility with the community).This should not be surprising as there is a strong interdependence between the WB and the US government (Left Business Observer, 1999). What is not to be done: a third way for comparative health research Social capital has been explicitly associated with Third Way social policies in the US and in the EU as well (Szreter, 1999). The Third Way, as in the New Labour or New Democrat governments and their intellectuals (Robert Reich, Anthony Giddens) has been associated with the reduced role of the state, privatization of social services, labour market exibility, non-governmental organizations, modern philanthropy and the demise of the welfare state (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a). Critics of the Third Way have argued that instead of representing a new set of policies by social-democratic parties, it represents a capitulation to the political right that leads to greater social inequalities (Albo & Zuege, 1999; Muntaner & Lynch, 1999a, 1999b). Albo & Zuege have argued that the failures of European social democracy in the seventies (e.g., Swedens Meidner plan) and early eighties (e.g., Mitterrands U turn) sent them into a path of retreat, accommodation and confusion from which they still have to recover.The Third Way rhetoric, more often de ned by what it is not than by what it is (Giddens, 1994), would be part of a search for a big idea that would ensure a durable political base for social-democratic parties in the new European capitalism. It is this potential role for social capital in public health that we think should be avoided (Muntaner & Lynch, 1999b). In the wake of recent elections in Europe, some analysts are arguing that support for Third Way policies is fading, most notably in Germany (Singer, 1999). If that were to be the case, the fortunes of social capital in public health could follow, at least in the EU where governments have been more responsible to egalitarian pressures from working class parties (Navarro, 1999).This is less likely to occur in the US where government is more insulated from egalitarian working class politics (Navarro, 1994).Within public health, rather than discarding structural inequalities such as gender, race and class as outmoded materialism, in favour of psychosocial

120 C. Muntaner et al. constructs such as social cohesion (Wilkinson, 1999), a much more fruitful strategy would be to seize the opportunity that social capital brings to integrate sociology and economics into the field of social inequalities in health. For example, the Marxian tradition of class inequality (Wright, 1997) could be integrated with the Weberian tradition of institutional social capital (Evans, 1995). The institutional view of social capital stresses how states operate: some states are efficient or inef cient, others are strong or weak.The role of political institutions such as parties, the judicial system, how the executive and legislative branches of governments operate (e.g., the rationalization of state bureaucracies) become central to understanding how states are formed (Evans, 1995). From a Marxian perspective on the other hand, class inequality guides the analysis of the state. How does the capitalist class in uence the legislative, administrative and executive branches of government? What are the class alliances (capitalist vs. working class) and splits among different segments of the capitalist class (financial vs. industrial) that affect government function or the relationship between the capitalist class and state elites? (Kadushin, 1995). At least the institutional approach to social capital favoured by Woolcock (1998) seems to be open to this kind of integration (e.g., Evans, 1995). But then, as public health scholars and activists, should we place false hopes on initiatives heralded by institutions (Amin, 1997) that have helped generate the health inequalities that we want to eliminate? References
Albo, G. & Zuege, A. (1999) European capitalism today: between the Euro and the third way, Monthly Review, 51(3), pp. 100119. Alderson, A. S. & Nielsen, F. (1999) Income inequality, development, and dependence: a reconsideration, American Sociological Review, 64(4), pp. 606631. Amin, S. (1997) Capitalism In the Age of Globalization: The Management of Contemporary Society (Atlantic Highlands, NJ, Zed Books). Aneshensel, C. S. & Sucoff, C. A. (1996) The neighborhood context of adolescent mental health, J Health & Soc Behaviour, 37, pp. 293310. Baum, F. (1997) Public health and civil society: understanding and valuing the connection, Aust J Public Health, 21, pp. 673675. Baum, F. (1999) Social capital: is it good for your health? Issues for a public health agenda, J Epidemiol Community Health, 53, pp. 195196. Borjas, G. J. (1992) Ethnic capital and intergenerational mobility, The Quarterly Jounal of Economics, 107(1), pp. 123150. Brines, J. (1999) The ties the bind: principles of cohesion in cohabitation and marriage, American Sociological Review, 64(3), pp. 333355. Carroll, L. (1999) The Complete Works of Lewis Carrol (Harmondsworth, Penguin). Chomsky, N. (1999a) The new military humanism: lessons from Kosovo, In These Times, 23(21), pp. 711. Chomsky, N. (1999b) Pro t Over People: Neoliberalism and Global Order (New York, Seven Stories Press). Coleman, J. (1990) Foundations of Social Theory (Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press). Collier, P. (1998) Social Capital and Poverty (Washington, DC, The World Bank, Social Capital Initiative). Cooper, H., Arber, S. & Ginn, J. (1999) The In uence of Social Support and Social Capital on Health (London, Health Education Authority).

Social capital and the third way in public health 121


Dixon, W. J. & Boswell, T. (1996) Dependency, disarticulation, and denominator effects: another look at foreign capital penetration, American Journal of Sociology, 102, pp. 54362. Economist (1999) Fueling Russias economy. Online: http://www.economist.com/editorial/justforyou/19990828/1d6020.html. Elster, J. (1993) Political Psychology (New York, Cambridge University Press). Erikson, B. H. (1996) Culture, class and connections, American Journal of Sociology, 102, pp.217251. Etzioni, A. & George, R. P. (1999) Virtue and the state: a dialogue between a commmunitarian and a social conservative, The Responsive Community, 9(2), pp. 5456. Evans, P. (1995) Embedded Autonomy (Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press). Fullilove, M. T. (1998) Promoting social cohesion to improve health, Journal Am Med Womens Assoc, 53(2), pp. 7276. Galbraith, J. K. (1999) The Crisis of Globalization. Dissent, Spring, pp. 1319. Giddens, A. (1994) Beyond Left and Right (California, Stanford University Press). Gould, R. V. (1991) Multiple networks and mobilization in the Paris commune, 1871, American Sociological Review, 56, pp. 716729. Gould, R. V. (1993) Trade cohesion, class unity, and urban insurrection, American Journal of Sociology, 98, pp. 721754. Granovetter, M. (1973) The strength of weak ties , American Journal of Sociology, 78, pp. 13601380 Grootaert, C. (1997) Social Capital: The Missing Link? In Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally Sustainable Development. Environmentally Sustainable Development Studies and Monographs Series No. 7 (Washington, DC, The World Bank). Havel, V. (1999) Beyond the nation-state, The Responsive Community, 9(3), pp. 2633. Hawe, P. & Shiell, A. (2000) Social capital and health promotion: a review, Social Science and Medicine, 51, pp. 871885. Hayes, M.V. & Dunn, J.R. (2000) On the currency of social capital in health inequalities. Simon Fraser University, unpublished paper. Jackman, R. W. et al. (1996) A renaissance of political culture, American Journal of Political Science, 40(3), pp. 632659. Jenson J. (1998) Mapping Social Cohesion: The State of Canadian Research (Ottawa, ON, Canadian Policy Research Networks). Kadushin, C. (1995) Friendship among the French nancial elite, American Soc Rev, 60, pp. 202221. Kaplan, G. A. (1995) Where do shared pathways lead? Some reflections on a research agenda, Psychosomatic Medicine, 57, pp. 208212. Kaufman, J. (1999) Three views of associationalism in 19th century America: an empirical examination, American Journal of Sociology, 104(5), pp. 12961345. Kawachi, I. & Berkman, L. (2000) Social cohesion, social capital and health. In: Berkman L. F., & Kawachi, I. (eds.) Social Epidemiology (New York, Oxford University Press). Kawachi, I., Kennedy, B.P. & Wilkinson, G. (1999) Crime: social disorganization and relative deprivation, Social Science & Medicine, 48, pp. 719731. Kawachi, I., Kennedy, B. & Pothrow-Smith, D. (1997a) Social capital, income inequality, and mortality, American Journal of Public Health, 87(9), pp. 14911498. Kawachi, I., Kennedy, B. & Lochner, K. (1997b) Long live community. Social capital as public health. American Prospect, NovDec 97, pp. 5659. Kawachi, I., & Kennedy, B. (1997) Health and social cohesion: why care about income inequality?, BMJ, 314, pp. 10371039. Kennedy, B. P., Kawachi, I, & Brainerd, E. (1999) The role of social capital in the Russian mortality crisis. World Development, 26(11), pp. 20292043. Kentor, J. (1998) The long-term effects of foreign investment dependence on economic growth, 19401990, American Journal of Sociology, 103, pp. 10241046. Knack, S. & Keefer, P. (1997) Does social capital have an economic pay off? A cross-country investigation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, pp. 12511288. Kolko, G. (1999) Ravaging the poor: the international monetary fund indicted by its own data, International Journal of Health Services, 29(1), pp. 5157.

122 C. Muntaner et al.


Koopman, J. S. & Lynch, J. W. (1999). Individual causal models and population systems models in epidemiology, American Journal of Public Health, 89, pp. 11701175. Krieger, N. (1994) Epidemiology and the web of causation: has anyone seem the spider?, Social Science and Medicine, 39, pp. 887903. Lavis, J. N. & Stoddart, G. L. (1999) Social Cohesion and Health (Toronto, Canada: Canadian Institute for Advanced Research, Program in Population Health). Left Business Observer (1999) Money. The Holy Trinity: Rubin, Greenspan, Summers, 90, pp.67. Lewis, O. (1998) The culture of poverty, Society, 35, pp. 79. Lomas, J. (1998) Social capital and health: implications for public health and epidemiology. Soc Sci Med, 47, pp. 11811188. Lynch, J. W. & Kaplan, G. A. (1997) Wither studies on the socioeconomic foundations of population health?, Am. J Public Health, 87, pp.14091411. Lynch, J. W., Kaplan, G. A. & Salonen, J. T. (1997) Why do poor people behave poorly? Variations in adult health behaviour and psychosocial characteristics, by stage of the socioeconomic lifecourse, Soc Sci Med, 44, pp. 809820. Lynch, J. W., Due, P., Muntaner, C. & Davey Smith, G. (2000) Social capital: is it a good investment strategy for public health? Journal of Epidemology and Community Health, 54, pp. 404408. Marjoribanks, K. (1999) Family human and social capital and young adults educational attainment and occupational aspirations, Psychological Reports, 69(1), pp. 237238. Marmot, M. & Theorell T. (1988) Social class and cardiovascular disease: the contribution of work, International Journal of Health Services, 18(4), pp. 659674. Marmot, M. (1998) Improvement of the social environment to improve health. The Lancet, 351, pp. 5760. Matthews, S., Stansfeld, S. & Power, C. (1999) Social support at age 33: the in uence of gender, employment status and social class, Social Science and Medicine, 49, pp. 133142. Muntaner, C. & OCampo, P. (1993) A critical appraisal of the Demand/Control model of the psychosocial work environment: epistemological, social, behavioral and class considerations, Social Science and Medicine, 36, pp. 15091517. Muntaner, C. (1999a) Teaching social inequalities in health: barriers and opportunities. Scandinavian Journal of Public Health, 27, pp. 161165. Muntaner, C. (1999b) Invited commentary: social mechanisms, race and social epidemiology, American Journal of Epidemiology, 150(2), pp. 121126. Muntaner, C. (2000) Applied epidemiology, Journal of Public Health Policy, 21(1), pp. 99102. Muntaner, C. & Lynch, J. (1999a) Income inequality and social cohesion versus class relations: a critique of Wilkinsons neo-Durkheimian research program, International Journal of Health Services, 29, pp. 5982. Muntaner, C. & Lynch, J. (1999b) The social class determinants of income inequality and social cohesion Part I: further comments on Wilkinsons reply, International Journal of Health Services, 29(4), pp. 699715. Muntaner, C., Nieto, J. & O Campo, P. (1997) Additional clari cation re: on race, social class, and epidemiologic research, American Journal of Epidemiology, 146(7), pp. 607608. Muntaner, C., Oates, G. & Lynch, J. (1999) The social class determinants of income inequality and social cohesion Part 2: presentation of an alternative model, International Journal of Health Services, 29(4), pp. 715732. Mustard, J. F. (1996) Health and Social Capital in Health and Social Organization: Towards a Health Policy for the 21st Century, (New York, Routledge). Navarro, V. (1994) The Politics of Health Policy (Amityville, NY, Baywood). Navarro, V. (1999) The political economy of the welfare state in developed capitalist countries, International Journal of Health Services, 29, pp. 150. Ostrom, E. (1999) Revisiting the commons: local lessons, global challenges, Science, 284, pp. 278282. Pattillo, M. E. (1998) Sweet mothers and gangbangers: managing crime in a black middle-class neighborhood, Social Forces, 76(3), pp. 747774.

Social capital and the third way in public health 123


Paxton, P. (1999) Is social capital declining in the United States? A multiple indicator assessment, American Journal of Sociology, 105(1), 88127. Persell, C. H., Catsambis, S. & Cookson, P. W. (1992) Differential asset conversion: class and gendered pathways to selective colleges, Sociology of Education, 65(3), pp. 208225. Portes, A. (1998) Social capital: its origins and applications in contemporary sociology, Annual Review of Sociology, 24, pp. 124. Proudfoot, J. & Guest, D. (1997) Effect of cognitive behavioural training on job- nding among long-term unemployed people, Lancet, 350 (9071), pp. 96100. Putnam, R. (1995a) Bowling alone: Americas declining social capital, Journal of Democracy, 6(1), pp. 6578. Putnam, R. (1995b) The prosperous community: social capital and public life, The American Prospect, Spring, pp. 2740. Putnam, R., Leonardi, R. & Nanetti, R. (1993) Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, Princeton University Press). Rose, G. (1985) Sick individuals and sick populations, International Journal of Epidemiol, 14, pp. 3238. Sampson, R. J., Raudenbush, S. W. & Earls, F. (1997) Neighborhoods and violent crime: a multilevel study of collective ef cacy, Science, 277, pp. 918924. Schneider, M. et al. (1997) Networks to nowhere: segregation and strati cation in networks of information about schools, American Journal of Political Science, 41(4), pp. 12011223. Singer, D. (1999) Third way dead end? (Editorial), The Nation, July 5. Skocpol, T. (1999) Associations without members, The American Prospect, 45, pp. 6673. Smith, T. (1997) Factors relating to misanthropy in contemporary American society, Social Science Research, 26, pp. 170196. Stiglitz, J. (1996) Some lessons from the East Asian miracle, The World Bank Research Observer, 11, pp. 151178. Stiglitz, J. (1997) An agenda for development for the twenty- rst century. In: Pleskovic, B. & Stiglitz, J. (eds) Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics 1997 (Washington, DC, The World Bank). Stoto, M. A. (1999) Sharing responsibility for the publics health, Public Health Reports, 114, pp. 231235. Szreter, S. (1999) A new political economy for New Labour The importance of social capital, Renewal, 7, pp. 3044. de Tocqueville, A. (1969) Democracy in America (New York, Anchor Books). First edition 1835. The World Bank Group (1999a) Social Capital for Development. The World Bank Group (1999b) World Bank Calls for a Narrowing of the Knowledge Gap between Rich and Poor . Tijhuis, M. A., Flap, H. D. Foets, M. & Groenewegen, P. P. (1995) Social support and stressful events in two dimensions: life events and illness as an event, Soc Sci Med, 40, pp. 15131526. Valette, J. (1999). Larry Summers War Against the Earth. On-line: http//:www.counterpunch.org/summers.html. Wainwright, D. (1996) The political transformation of the health inequalities debate, Critical Social Policy, 16, pp. 6782. Warner, W. L. (1960) Social Class in America (New York, Harper and Row). Warren, M. R. (1994) Exploitation or cooperation? The political basis of regional variation in the Italian informal economy, Politics & Society, 22(1), p. 89. Wedel, J. R. (1998) Collision and Collusion. The Strange Case of Western Aid to Eastern Europe 19891998 (London, St. Martin Press). Wilkinson, R. G. (1996) Unhealthy Societies: The Af ictions of Inequality (Routledge, London). Wilkinson, R.G. (1999) Income inequality, social cohesion, and health: clarifying the theory a reply to Muntaner and Lynch, International Journal of Health Services, 29, pp. 525543. Wilkinson R. G, Kawachi, I. & Kennedy, B. (1998a) Mortality, the social environment, crime and violence, Sociol Health and Illness, 20(5), pp. 578 597.

124 C. Muntaner et al.


Wilkinson, R. G., Kawachi, I. & Kennedy, B. (1998b) Morality, the social environment and violence. In: Bartley, M., Blane, D., Davey Smith G. (eds.) The Sociology of Health Inequalities (Oxford: Blackwell Publishers). Wing, S. (1998) Whose epidemiology, whose health?, International Journal of Health Services, 28(2), pp. 241252. Woolcock, M. (1998) Social capital and economic development: a critical review, Theory and Society, 27, pp. 151208 Wright, E. O. (1997) Class Counts. Comparative Studies in Class Analysis (New York: Cambridge University Press). Zweigenhaft, R. L. (1993) Accumulation of cultural and social capital, Social Spectrum, 13, pp. 365376.

También podría gustarte