Está en la página 1de 17

2 March 2011

Demystifying Financial Derivatives:


Interest Rate Swaps and Municipal Derivatives
1

By Dr. Massimiliano De Santis Summary


This paper reviews the economics of interest rate swaps and other interest rate derivatives. We
begin by illustrating how interest rate swaps work and how they can be used to expand the set
of financing options available to a company, to manage exposure to interest rate risks, and to
speculate on interest rate expectations. Using recent municipal swaps as an example, we then
illustrate potential issues of contention between swap counterparties and review the economic
principles behind them.

While interest rate swaps offer a borrower potential cost savings justifiable on economic
grounds, they may also expose him to risks not present in other financing alternatives. For
example, a borrower that issues revolving debt and enters into a swap to hedge against interest
rate changes is not in the same position of a borrower that borrows long-term at the same
rate. The former is subject to changes in his credit risk whereas the latter is not. The Jefferson
County, Alabama case reviewed in this paper is an example of a realization of this risk.

When interest rate swaps are used to hedge a company’s exposure to interest rate risk, their
ex-post performance in terms of financing costs may be inferior to an alternative that leaves
a borrower exposed to interest rate risk. We argue that the economic soundness of a swap
should be evaluated on an ex-ante basis, taking into account its risk-return trade-off relative to
alternative financing options.

We also review some common swap pricing practices important in determining the value of
a swap and understanding swap-dealer fees. While a standard principle in swap pricing is
the mid-market pricing, or zero net present value, in practice the net present value of a swap
at inception is positive for a dealer. We review the main adjustments dealers make to arrive
at a fair market value, including credit risk, profit margins, and liquidity adjustments. The
adjustments should rely on sound economic models, and the models should make appropriate
risk adjustments to expected losses and expected defaults.
I. Introduction
While the role of financial markets in facilitating lending and providing investment capital to
business often steals the limelight, the role of the financial system in facilitating the separation
and trade of economic risks is no less essential to economic growth. The idea is that trading
risks lowers the cost of financing risky projects by separating one risk from another and placing
each with the party that is able to bear it at the lowest cost. Financial derivatives are contracts
that facilitate the separation and trade of economic risks.2

This paper reviews the economic benefits of one type of contract designed to trade in risk,
interest rate swaps, and related interest rate derivatives. By allowing two parties to swap cash
flows, interest rate derivatives expand the set of financing options available to borrowers. This
allows them to lower financing costs, manage mismatches between assets and liabilities, and
manage their exposure to interest rate risk. Some of the earliest interest rate swaps were done
by Sallie Mae in the early 1980s with the goal of reducing the duration of its liabilities. Since
then, the market for interest rate derivatives has increased exponentially. According to the
Bank for International Settlements (BIS), the global notional amount of interest rate derivatives
(including interest rate swaps and other derivatives described below) was about $347 trillion
as of June 2010.3 The amount was $51 trillion as of June 2000 according to the same source,
and only $182 billion in 1987, according to data from the International Swap and Derivatives
Association (ISDA).4

This paper is motivated in part by recent activity in the market for municipal interest-rate
derivatives. Just like companies in the private sector, states and local governments have sought
to benefit from interest rate swaps, and the market for municipal interest rate derivatives
has experienced similar growth. For example, today, 70% of issuers of variable-rate demand
obligations (VRDOs), a certain type of long-term floating rate bond, have entered into interest
rate swaps.5 With the increased usage, the economic soundness of some municipal swap
transactions has been questioned recently, and some local governments are bringing lawsuits
against the financial institutions that wrote the swaps. A wave of allegedly suspect municipal
swap transactions has surfaced both in the US and Europe, and Italy in particular. We review
some of the economic aspects of current and potential litigation in Section III.

Like most financial assets, interest rate swaps have inherent risks. Some of these risks can be
off-set by other risks on the balance sheet of a business or a government entity, in which case
the swap can be used as a hedging instrument. Other risks are swap-specific though, and
may or may not be easily mitigated. All these risks need to be considered in deciding among
alternative financing options. Further, when using swaps as hedging instruments, a user gives
up potential gains in some states of the world in exchange for protection from potential losses
in other states of the world. This implies that there may be a difference between ex-ante
optimality and ex-post performance of a given swap. Questions related to risks, optimality, and
performance of swaps are elements of contention in recent swap litigation.

The next section describes the basic functioning of a (plain vanilla) interest rate swap. Section
III describes the use of interest rate swaps by municipalities, and gives a high-level overview of
recent litigation involving municipal interest rate swaps in the US. We also give an overview of
similar litigation, some with potentially high stakes, brought by local governments in Italy. In
Section IV we analyze the economic benefits of swaps and discuss economic aspects of interest
rate swaps that are of relevance in current and potential swap litigation.

www.nera.com 2
II. Interest Rate Swaps
An interest rate swap is a periodic exchange of fixed coupon payments by one counterparty
(called the fixed-rate payer) in return for variable-rate payments by another counterparty
(called the floating-rate payer), until a stated maturity.6

By combining interest rate swaps with alternative financing options, interest rate swaps increase
the number of ways in which a firm can borrow. This can lead to lower borrowing costs and
better interest rate risk management. The following example explains how a swap between two
counterparties works.

A relatively risky borrower, BBB Corp., needs a fixed rate to finance new long-term investment.
The company can finance the investment either by borrowing from a bank or in the direct
market by issuing bonds. The company is able to borrow from the bank at a variable rate of
LIBOR + 2%.7 Because it is a company with a relatively large default risk, it can only issue bonds
at a rate of 10%. Next, consider a good credit risk, AAA Corp., which would like to borrow at
a variable rate. Because it has high credit ratings and a low probability of default, the company
pays LIBOR + 1% on its bank loans and can issue bonds at a rate of 7%.

Assuming LIBOR is 5%, the following table shows the interest rates faced by the two companies
in the two different markets:

Table 1. Hypothetical Interest Rates on AAA Corp. and BBB Corp.’s Obligations

Bank Loan Bonds


(Short Term) (Long Term)

BBB Corp. 7.00% 11.00%
AAA Corp. 6.00% 7.00%

Quality Spread (difference) 1.00% 4.00%

BBB Corp. pays more to borrow in both markets. However, the bond market requires a quality
spread 3% larger than the bank loan market (4% - 1%). BBB Corp. is said to have a comparative
advantage in the bank loans market, while AAA Corp. is said to have a comparative advantage
in the bond market.

Without swaps, BBB Corp. can meet its financing needs by borrowing long term at 11%,
and AAA Corp. by taking a renewable bank loan at LIBOR + 1% (6%). Alternatively, they can
each borrow from the market in which they have a comparative advantage, and then swap
the payments.

Assume both companies need $10 million in fresh capital. BBB Corp. takes a renewable loan
at LIBOR + 2% (starting at 7%) from its bank; AAA Corp. issues a 10-year bond at a 7% rate.
Under the terms of the 10-year swap for a $10 million notional principal, BBB Corp. pays a fixed
rate of 9% to AAA Corp., and AAA Corp. pays 2% over LIBOR to BBB Corp.

www.nera.com 3
Notice the fixed rate paid by BBB Corp. is two percentage points below the rate it would pay if
it issued 10-year bonds. AAA Corp. pays LIBOR + 2% in the swap, but receives a spread of 2%
over its fixed interest payment in the bond market from BBB Corp., so it ends up paying LIBOR
after the swap, a gain of one percentage point. The total potential gain from trade is three
percentage points. We analyze this potential gain from swaps in more detail in Section IV.B.

Figure 1. An Interest Rate Swap Between BBB Corp. and AAA Corp.

Net Cost: 9% Net Cost: LIBOR


9%

BBB Corp. AAA Corp.

LIBOR + 2%

LIBOR + 2% 7%

Bond
Bank
Holders

A. Pricing vs. Value of a Swap


In the example above, we have taken the fixed rate on the swap as given. This rate depends
on several factors, some of which are explained below. Determining the fixed rate at inception
is referred to as pricing of the swap. The swap is priced so that there is no upfront cash
exchange between the parties involved.

In practice, the fixed and floating payments are offset (or netted) against each other as
of each payment date, and the party paying the higher rate of interest remits a payment
to the counterparty equal to the notional amount multiplied by the difference between
the interest rates. So that if the swap rate (9% in our example) is greater than LIBOR, the
fixed-rate payer pays

(swap rate – LIBOR) × notional principal.

If LIBOR is greater than the swap rate, the floating-rate payer pays

(LIBOR – swap rate) × notional principal.8

www.nera.com 4
The swap rate determined at the inception of the swap reflects, among other things, market
expectations about future LIBOR rates and about the future ability of both payers to make the
payments. The rate at inception makes the swap a fair wager so that neither party is favored
at the expense of the other. Supply and demand in the market for swaps will establish a rate
that the market considers to be fair. At this rate, given market expectations about the future
payments, the net present value of the swap contract is zero.

The swap rate is determined by market conditions and expectations at inception. When these
conditions change, the rate for a new swap—the rate at which its net present value is zero—
also changes. This implies that the value of an old swap, whose rate is contractually fixed,
changes over time, and could become either positive or negative depending on the new
swap rate.

Consider the above example between BBB Corp. and AAA Corp. again. Suppose that at some
point after the swap contract is signed, interest rates are lower so that both companies could
borrow at a lower rate in both markets. Also assume that rates are such that the rate for a new
swap is 8%. Because the rate on the old swap is contractually fixed at 9%, BBB Corp., the fixed-
rate payer, would be willing to pay to cancel the old swap and enter into a new one at 8%. The
net present value of the old swap with a 9% rate is negative to the fixed-rate payer.

Conversely, if the rate for a new swap (the new prevailing swap rate) is 10%, the fixed-rate
payer gains from the old swap, and now AAA Corp. would be willing to pay to cancel the
swap. The net present value of the old swap is positive to the fixed-rate payer and the swap is
said to be in the money. To summarize:

The value of an outstanding swap to a fixed-rate payer is positively correlated with changes in
market interest rates. When interest rates increase, the value of the swap increases, and when
interest rates decrease, the value of the swap decreases.

B. Hedging and Speculating Using Swaps


The correlation between swap values and interest rates can be used to both hedge interest rate
risk and speculate on interest rate fluctuations.

Consider again the net cash flows of the two swap counterparties. At each payment date,
which party makes a payment depends on the LIBOR rate at the time. So, contingent on the
LIBOR rates over the life of a swap, the swap will result in a loss or a gain, ex-post. For a
variable rate borrower like BBB Corp.—someone that has an underlying position—this loss
or gain is completely off-set by the variable payments that also depend on LIBOR; in net, the
borrower pays the fixed rate at each date, so he is completely hedged.9

Swaps can also be used to transform the nature of a company’s balance sheet assets, allowing
a company to obtain the desired exposure to interest rates. For example, a company that owns
long-term assets yielding a fixed rate is subject to interest rate risk as the value of those assets is
negatively correlated to interest rates. So to hedge against a capital loss when interest rates fall,
the company can swap the fixed interest payments for floating interest payments.10

www.nera.com 5
For various reasons—including risk management, regulatory requirements, and debt
restructuring—companies and local governments routinely use interest rate swaps to hedge
their interest rate exposure. This practice has increased in the last decade.

As with any other financial instrument, swaps can also be used to speculate. An investor
is taking a speculative position if he does not have a corresponding underlying position (an
asset or a liability to hedge). His swap position is motivated solely by the prospect of a change
in value in the swap as a result of changing interest rates. A speculator may take a fixed-rate
payer position if he expects interest rates to rise or a floating-rate payer position if he expects
rates to decline.

III. Use of Interest Rate Swaps by Municipalities and Interest Rate


Swaps Litigation
Municipalities have several different options in issuing debt to generate needed cash flows.
Typically, municipalities issue short-term notes in anticipation of upcoming revenue, a practice
that allows them to cover temporary deficits. Long-term bonds, on the other hand, are issued
to finance ongoing budget deficits arising from investments in construction or other capital
projects. Whether issuing long- or short-term debt, municipalities must also decide on whether
to use a fixed or a floating rate. Furthermore, within each of these categories, there exist
several different types of securities. This can lead to complicated balance sheets with numerous
revenue obligations, all with different cash flow characteristics.

Other Swaps
There are many variations that can be applied to the plain vanilla fixed-for-floating interest rate swap contract. The
following are just a few, more common examples. In an amortizing swap, the principal notional is reduced over time
in a pre-determined way, often timed to match the amortization schedule of existing loans. The principal notional can
also increase over time, as in a step-up swap.

Swaps can be designed to exchange two floating payments that reference two different rates, as in basis (or floating-
to-floating) swaps. These serve to reduce basis risk, the risk that arises from an imperfect match between a
derivative contract (which may depend on LIBOR) and the underlying position, e.g., an asset returning a variable rate
based on commercial paper rates, or a liability with interest rates linked to short-term US Treasuries.

Notional amounts can be based on different currencies, as in a currency swap. These can be designed in any
combination of fixed and floating payments (fixed-for-fixed, fixed-for-floating, floating-for-floating).

Options on swaps and forward swaps are also traded. With a swaption, a party can acquire the right, at a future
time, to enter into a swap at a predetermined rate. In a forward swap, the two parties agree to exchange payments
starting at a future date.

Swaps are sometimes combined with other interest rate options. For example, a floating rate payer can limit his/her
interest rate payments with a ceiling, or can sell part of his/her gains from low interest rate payments with a floor.
Or s/he can collar his/her payments with both a floor and a ceiling.

www.nera.com 6
A municipality may find it useful to change the structure of some of its bonds in order to better
match its changing asset positions.11 Interest rate swaps can be useful to change floating-rate
debt into fixed-rate, or vice versa.

A study conducted by the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) in 2004 shows that 94%
of all municipal securities had a fixed coupon (77% by principal amount).12 However, relative to
fixed-rate securities, variable-rate securities were more likely to be long term.13 To hedge against
the risk of a rising interest rate, municipalities can enter into floating-to-fixed swap agreements,
wherein they receive a variable interest rate and pay a fixed rate. In some cases, this can also
provide the municipality with a lower cost of borrowing than simply issuing fixed-rate debt.14
For example, today, 70% of issuers of VRDOs, a certain type of long-term floating rate bond,
have entered into floating-to-fixed swaps.15 On the other hand, municipalities can also utilize
fixed-to-floating swaps on their fixed-rate debt depending on their overall hedging needs. For
municipalities, like private companies, swaps are a useful tool for liability management and they
can use them to restructure the existing debt mix any time they feel it is unbalanced.

A. US Municipal Interest Rate Derivatives Litigation


Recent changes in reference interest rates have caused losses in swap positions taken by
hundreds of US municipalities.

With the fall in interest rates brought by the recent global financial crisis, the municipalities
are losing money on floating-to-fixed swap agreements they made during the bull market to
protect themselves against rising interest rates.16 In some cases, even with falling interest rates,
municipalities have found that the floating payments they make on their debt have increased,
due to downgrades to the credit companies insuring the debt.17 To compound the problem,
unwinding or terminating the swaps may be costly. For instance, the city of Oakland, California,
under an interest rate swap with Goldman Sachs, stands to pay a reported $5 million in 2010;
however, terminating the swap would cost an estimated $19 million.18

Many of the cases in which municipalities have suffered losses due to swap agreements have
led to litigation against banks, resulting in settlements or the restructuring of swap agreements
to provide more favorable terms to the municipalities. In a 2009 case, the Alabama Public
School and College Authority (APSCA) sued to void a swaption it had sold to JPMorgan and
refused to make payments on this swaption until a court decision had been made.19 The APSCA
agreed to pay $19 million in a settlement with JPMorgan on 28 December 2010.20 Many other
municipalities have pursued similar litigation, alleging that banks have understated the riskiness
of interest rate swaps.

In 2008, there were 136 defaults on municipal securities.21 The largest among these was
the default on $3.8 billion worth of sewer bonds by Jefferson County, Alabama.22 Like many
other municipalities, the county lost money on floating-to-fixed interest rate swaps following
the credit crisis.23 This has led to several lawsuits filed by the citizens of Jefferson County—
not only against Wall Street banks, but also against officials of the municipality. Chief among
the complaints alleged were that “unscrupulous investment bankers” took advantage of
the county’s lack of financial knowledge and that county commissioners neglected their
fiduciary duties.24

www.nera.com 7
Common among the above cited cases is the allegation that financial institutions have misled
or misrepresented municipalities about the risks involved with interest rate swaps and related
derivatives. In other litigation, the fees and profits that the banks made are called into question.
For example, in a lawsuit filed in August 2008, the Erie City School District in Philadelphia,
Pennsylvania alleged that JPMorgan and a Pennsylvania financial adviser colluded to charge
undisclosed fees on swaptions the municipality sold to the bank.25

B. Italian Interest Rate Derivatives Litigation


Swaps between local governments and financial institutions are being investigated throughout
Italy by the “Guardia di Finanza,” the Italian police force under the authority of the Ministry
of Economy and Finance. As of 1 September 2010, swaps between 53 local governments and
several major banks had been investigated. The local governments include large cities, like
Milan, Rome, Florence, and Naples, and small ones, like Polino, a town of 290 people,26 as well
as the regional governments of Piedmont, Tuscany, and Lazio. In some cases charges have been
pressed, and at least the Milan case went to trial in May 2010 (no decision has been reached
yet). The banks involved in the Milan deal were Deutsche Bank, JP Morgan, DEPFA, and UBS.

As of 30 June 2010, almost 700 local governments had outstanding swap contracts for a total
notional principal of about €35 billion.27 Banca d’Italia statistics show that local governments’
derivative transactions with negative market value (including interest and credit derivatives)
add up to about €1.2 billion, as of June 2010. As of the same date, derivative transactions with
positive market value add up to about €143 million.28

Derivative transactions under investigation include fixed-to-floating and floating-to-fixed swaps,


step-up swaps, amortizing swaps, interest rate floors, ceilings, and interest rate collars.

The City of Milan issued a €1.68 billion, 30-year, fixed-rate bond in 2005 to retire a number
of existing loans. In connection with the bond issuance, it swapped the fixed bond payments
for “collared” variable payments (a fixed-to-floating with collar swap). Under the collared swap
agreement, the city pays a variable rate that is allowed to vary in reference to Euribor within the
boundaries of the collar. Milan prosecutors started investigating the transactions in June 2008
and the case culminated in the first criminal case against banks in Europe.29

There are two main allegations in the case. The first has to do with representations made by the
banks about the riskiness of the swap and its effect on the overall cost of debt. The city alleges
that the banks represented that refinancing with the swap would lower the city’s overall cost
of debt. The second main allegation is that the pricing of the swap was unfavorable to the city,
given that the banks booked an allegedly large profit when the swap was issued.30

The Milan case is seen as a litmus test for other Italian municipalities that have large negative
market value on their swaps, and the ruling could serve as a catalyst for many future lawsuits.

www.nera.com 8
Investigations and allegations in other current cases are similar. For example, in the Polino case,
the debt restructuring and the collared swaps of the town are effectively the same as the ones
in Milan, although with slightly higher interest rates. The investigation in progress in Rome
involves several derivative transactions connected to the issuance of a fixed-rate €1.4 million
bond. The derivatives include an amortizing swap, a fixed-to-fixed step-up swap, and a fixed-
to-variable swap. The swaps are reported to have a negative value as of September 2009.31
The investigation, carried on by the Rome Prosecutor office, is examining whether the
transactions constituted appropriate hedges, and whether the banks booked excessive profits
from the transactions.32

Litigation involving municipal interest rate swaps is not new. Between 1987 and 1989, the
London Borough of Hammersmith and Fulham undertook a total of 592 swap transactions with
a notional value of over £6 billion, at some point about 20 times its total debt.33 The London
High Court ruled in 1989 that the swap agreements were not legal because the trades were
deemed speculative, and not just hedges.34 The case went all the way to the House of Lords,
which decided that the swap agreements were unlawful and the transactions were void.

IV. Economic Analysis


We have seen above that in current and potential litigation, two main aspects of swaps are
in contention. The first is whether the swaps were sound economic choices, once the risk-
return trade-off offered by the swaps is taken into account. The second element of contention
has to do with the pricing of the swap. In this section, we examine the main economic and
financial considerations of optimal swap decisions, highlighting potential trade-offs between
risk and reward. We then expand on the main aspects of swap pricing to understand the main
determinants of bank fees.

A. Comparing Financing Alternatives


Whether a borrower should pay a fixed rate or a variable rate depends on his cash flow needs
subject to risk management considerations like balance sheet gaps between assets and liabilities
and cash flow hedging needs. Once a borrower has decided what type of financing fits his
needs best, swaps can be used to expand the set of available financing options. For example, if
the borrower desires a long-term fixed-rate loan, he can borrow directly in the bond market, or
borrow at a variable rate from a bank, and swap the floating rate for a fixed rate.35

In choosing between alternative financing and swap options, economic decision rules should be
based on the maximization of incremental firm value or, for a government agency, minimizing
financing costs, making appropriate risk-return considerations. For example, a floating-rate plus
swap option may result in a lower fixed rate than simple bond financing, but may leave the
borrower exposed to basis or other risks that we discuss below.

www.nera.com 9
B. Borrowing Costs
In the swap example of Section II, BBB Corp. and AAA Corp. exploited an apparently riskless
profit opportunity given by the difference in quality spreads between short-term and long-term
financing (a 3% quality difference). With the swap, BBB Corp. borrows long term at 9% instead
of the 11% without the swap, and AAA Corp. can borrow short-term at LIBOR instead of LIBOR
+ 1%. Why is it possible to lower the cost of financing using swaps? At least part of the answer
is that use of the swap leads to an efficient allocation of risks. Recall that our premise is that
BBB Corp. needs a 10-year fixed-rate loan. There are two risks associated with this loan: interest
rate risk and credit risk, and the two markets differ in their ability to bear these risks.

Relationship lenders like banks have an advantage in handling credit risk for small companies
with relatively higher risks of defaults like BBB Corp.: they may know more about the company,
they are better at monitoring, and are more flexible in dealing with repayment problems.
Because the bond market does not deal with the risks of small companies as well, bond
investors require a higher risk premium, reflected in a higher interest rate.

In contrast, typical bond investors—such as pension funds and life insurance companies—have
long-term liabilities, so long-term bonds match their liabilities and minimize interest rate risks.
As a result, the bond market is better suited to bear the interest rate risk inherent in a long-term
loan. On the other hand, banks typically have short-term liabilities on which they pay a variable
interest rate, and so are susceptible to interest rate risks when they lend long term.36

The swap allows credit risk to be separated from interest rate risk, and allows each risk to be
allocated to different markets according to their ability to handle the risks. The result is lower
financing costs for both parties.37

The example of BBB Corp. is relatively common. Typically, companies with good credit ratings
are able to borrow more cheaply than other borrowers, and their relative advantage is greatest
when borrowing at fixed rates for maturities of five years or longer.38

With highly developed financial markets, an important question is why there should be such an
apparent risk-free profit opportunity. The answer to this question is that BBB Corp. will borrow
at 9% only if it can continue to borrow short term at LIBOR + 2%. If BBB Corp.’s rating declines
over the life of the swap, its rate will be greater than 9%. So one reason why the quality spread
is higher for long-term bonds is that the financial markets expect BBB’s short-term spread over
LIBOR to rise over the life of the swap. In other words, the market expects the borrowing rate
to be higher than 9%, on average.

Similarly, AAA Corp. will borrow short term at LIBOR (instead of LIBOR + 1%) only if BBB Corp.
does not default. In case of default, AAA Corp. would either have to find another counterparty,
or borrow at LIBOR + 1%. Part of the difference in quality spreads between long-term and
short-term financing is the probability of a default by BBB.

To summarize, the lower fixed rate of a swap relative to long-term financing represents, in part,
compensation for risks that would not be faced by a borrower with long-term financing.

www.nera.com 10
C. Basis Risk
Typically, swap payments depend on a common reference rate like LIBOR.39 If the variable
interest rate payments of a borrower reference the same rate, the swap provides a perfect
hedge. But if the variable interest rate is not the same as LIBOR, the borrower faces what is
called basis risk. The borrower receives LIBOR, but his variable payments could be higher or
lower than LIBOR. In this case the hedge is not perfect and the borrower will not be able to
achieve exact fixed-rate payments. Basis risk and the choice of the reference rate should be
considered when making a financing decision.

As a solution to basis risk, the issuer can enter into what is called a cost-of-funds swap, where
the financial institution in the swap agrees to match the variable interest rate on the actual
obligation, at a cost. This eliminates basis risk but makes a swap less tradable and less liquid.
There may be other, external factors that can cause a mismatch between variable-rate
payments and swap payments. For example, as we have seen in the Jefferson County case, the
downgrade of a bond insurer could lead to a large increase in the variable interest rate without
a corresponding increase in the reference rate. To the bond issuer, this is ultimately a form
of basis risk, a risk that should be considered when entering into a swap agreement.

D. Ex-Ante vs. Ex-Post Considerations


Financing costs of different swaps and financing strategies will differ, ex-post, depending on
the behavior of interest rates. And a financing strategy that is optimal ex-ante can result in
higher financing costs ex-post. Consider a fixed-rate payer that has chosen, optimally, to issue
a variable rate obligation and swapped to fixed payments with a counterparty. If the variable
rate declines over the life of the swap, the borrower will find himself paying more with the
swap than he would have without the swap.

This does not necessarily mean that the swap was not an economically sound decision. In this
example, the purpose of the swap is to transform a variable-rate loan into a fixed-rate loan to
eliminate the risk of changing interest rates. With the swap, a borrower gives up the potential
gains from lower interest rates to avoid the potential losses from higher interest rates. The
potential gains/losses depend on future market conditions and the fixed rate determined at
inception. Competition in the swap market will ensure that the fixed rate at inception is such
that the swap is a fair wager, as explained in Section II.A.

E. Swap Value and Interest Rates


We have seen in Section II.A that as expectations and economic conditions change, the rate on
a new swap will differ from the rate on an old swap. In a competitive market, the change in the
swap rate will also affect the value of the old swap. Consider a plain vanilla swap that had value
of zero at inception, and suppose the rate on a new swap with the same maturity is lower than
the rate at inception. The market value of the swap from the fixed-rate-payer’s side must now
be negative. Otherwise, the fixed-rate payer could terminate the old swap, pocket its value, and
enter into a new swap at a lower rate. Similarly, if the swap rate goes up, the value of the old
swap will be positive.

www.nera.com 11
More generally, swap values depend directly on prevailing swap rates, which are affected by all
the interest rates with maturities up to the maturity of the swap, i.e., the yield curve of interest
rates.40 In contrast, swap values are not very sensitive to changes in the reference rate (like
LIBOR), all else equal. In this respect, interest rate swaps are similar to long-term bonds. For
example, the value of a floating-to-fixed swap will increase if the yield curve becomes steeper.41

In general, a hedger should not be concerned with this type of fluctuation in the value of the
swap. The fact that the value of the swap is negative at some point in time due to changes in
interest rates does not necessarily mean that the swap was a bad decision for a fixed-rate payer.
If it was determined at inception that a fixed-rate payment was optimal, the borrower’s interest
rate costs are exactly as expected.

However, certain value considerations should be made at the time of financing. Because the
hedging and financing needs of a company or government agency can change over time, it
is possible that the company or agency will need to unwind or restructure existing swaps at
a later date. In this case, it is important to understand the sensitivity of the swap to interest
rates, which can constitute a risk to the company or government agency. Because the value of a
swap responds to interest rate changes as a long-term bond with the same maturity, short-term
swaps may be preferable to long-term swaps in situations where hedging needs may change.

F. How the Swap Market Works


So far, we have abstracted from the question of how the two parties in a swap transaction
meet. The swap market is not an auction market organized through an exchange; rather, it is
a dealer or over-the-counter (OTC) market where swaps are traded under standard contractual
terms organized through the ISDA. In this market, any counterparty, like BBB Corp., negotiates
the contractual terms of the swap with a dealer. In the case of plain vanilla interest rate swaps,
only the fixed rate and the maturity need to be negotiated. While we have so far focused on
the floating-to-fixed (plain vanilla) swap, the OTC market trades a high number of interest rate
derivatives tailored to the particular needs of different counterparties.

On economic principles, the competitiveness of a market—and the prices formed in it—does


not depend on whether trading is through bilateral negotiation (as in the OTC market) or in an
organized exchange. How competitive a market is depends on the number of buyers and sellers
in the market, the information available to them, and the type of instrument being traded. For
plain vanilla interest rate swaps, bid and ask rates are widely reported, dealers are numerous,
and they compete for business. Bid-ask spreads in these markets tend to be low, on the order
of 3-4 basis points (100 basis points equal 1%), indicating relatively high liquidity and low profit
margins, both signs of a competitive market.42 Market prices are therefore good indicators of
fair value for most plain vanilla swaps between counterparties with good credit (AA or higher,
more on this below).

Dealers in the OTC market, mainly banks and securities firms, provide liquidity to the market
by standing ready to enter either side of a swap transaction at their quoted rates, without
waiting to find a counterparty. They also provide liquidity by allowing counterparties to cancel a
contract in exchange for an appropriate payment.

www.nera.com 12
To balance their positions and manage their exposure to interest rate risk, dealers will frequently
offset the positions by swapping their exposure with other dealers in the interdealer market.
Alternatively, market makers can hedge their positions on exchange-traded markets, like in the
T-bond futures market.

One particularly appealing feature of the OTC market is the willingness of the dealers to tailor
contracts to the needs of a counterparty. This allows a counterparty to hedge more precisely,
without incurring the risk involved with an imperfect hedge. Even if a tailored contract may be
less liquid relative to plain vanilla swaps or other options and futures traded on exchanges, for a
counterparty whose hedging needs are unlikely to change suddenly, the relative lack of liquidity
may be of secondary importance.

G. Mid-Market Pricing and Valuation


Dealers stand ready to write swap contracts with counterparties. This provides liquidity to the
market but leaves the dealers with certain risks and costs. To be profitable, dealers need to
pass these costs, along with a mark-up, to the counterparties in the swap. In practice, dealers
publish bid and ask swap rates at which they are willing to bid or offer a swap with another
dealer of good credit in the swap market (a AA credit or better). The bid rate is the fixed rate
paid by the dealer to a floating rate payer; the ask is the rate paid to the dealer by a fixed-rate
payer. The average between the bid and the ask is called mid-market swap rate. Mid-market
swap rates for different maturities make what is called the swap curve or “par” curve. The
mid-market swap rates have the property that the net present value of a swap between good
credit counterparties at inception is zero (hence the “par” rate). That is, the net present value of
the cash flows to the floating-rate payer is equal to the net present value of the cash flows to
the fixed-rate payer.

1. Adjustments to Pricing
To arrive at a swap rate for a non-dealer client, a dealer typically adds certain costs to the mid-
market rate. This model of pricing a swap is called mid-market pricing with adjustments.
Adjustments can vary depending on the counterparty and the type of transaction, and may
include adjustments for credit risk, hedging costs, administrative and other costs, liquidity, and
a profit margin.43 Typically, at the inception of the swap, no money changes hands between the
dealer and the counterparty. Dealers incorporate these cost adjustments into the fixed swap
rate, which will be higher (lower) than the mid-market rate for a fixed-rate payer (receiver). As a
result, the net present value of the swap at inception will not be zero. It will be positive for the
dealer, and negative for the swap counterparty.

To quantify the value added of the transaction, a dealer will subtract some of the costs
described above, like credit and hedging costs, from the positive value, and will arrive at a
measure known as initial net present value (INPV), which will typically be positive.44 This value is
a measure of the dealer’s compensation for the costs and risks involved in the swap transaction.

2. Credit Risk Adjustments


Consider a dealer that has entered into offsetting contracts with two counterparties. If neither
party defaults, the dealer is fully hedged. If one of the two parties defaults, the dealer still has
to honor the contract with the other party. Suppose a fixed-rate payer defaults. The dealer will
have to pay the floating-rate payer

www.nera.com 13
(swap rate – LIBOR) × notional principal

any time the swap rate is above LIBOR, and will receive

(LIBOR – swap rate) × notional principal

any time the swap rate is below LIBOR.

Recall that at inception, the swap rate is set so that the present value of the two streams of
contingent payments are equivalent. So, even with counterparties with higher risk, the risk of
default to a dealer is relatively small, although not zero, right after inception. As we move away
from inception though, with changes in interest rates, the net present value of the contingent
payments could be substantially different from zero, either positive or negative.

Consider the case of a fixed-rate payer that defaults. If the net present value to a fixed-rate
payer is negative, s/he will be expected to pay more than s/he expects to receive. These
payments will now fall on the financial institution that wrote the swap. If it wants to offset this
position, the financial institution will be asked to pay roughly the net present value amount
to induce a third party to accept the position. This amount represents the dealer’s expected
exposure. If the net present value is positive, it’s unlikely that the dealer would be able to
realize the gain, as the fixed-rate payer could sell the position and realize the gain before
default. This implies that the expected exposure conditional on a default follows the hockey-
stick pattern below as a function of the value of the swap to the fixed-rate payer.

Figure 2. Dealer Exposure Given Default as a Function of Swap Value

Dealer
Exposure

0 Swap Value to Fixed


Rate Payer

www.nera.com 14
Numerical simulation methods can be used, along with the payoff structure of the above
chart, to estimate a dealer’s expected exposure at any given time (when a default has not yet
occurred). The expected exposure can be used to adjust the pricing of the swap to account for
credit risk. There are two main sources of changes in the expected exposure, and therefore the
pricing adjustment: (i) interest rate changes and (ii) a change in the credit risk of the borrower.
The exposure can be large if, some time after inception, interest rates change or the credit
quality of the counterparty deteriorates.

The same considerations apply to a floating-rate payer, with the sign of contingent payments
(and the present value) reversed.

In addition to credit adjustments, financial institutions can manage their exposure to


counterparty risk by requiring that the counterparty posts collateral against the exposure.
Collateralization is very common in OTC derivatives and has been increasing over the years.45

3. Other Adjustments
When a market-maker writes a swap with a counterparty, he does it without waiting to match
fixed-rate and floating-rate payers. This exposes the market maker to interest rate risk. And
balancing this risk through the inter-dealer market or exchange-traded contracts is costly.
A dealer will pass these hedging costs to its counterparties through the quoted rates. The
same situation arises when the market-maker agrees to cancel an existing swap. An example
of hedging costs is the fraction of the interdealer bid-ask spread a dealer would have to pay
to offset a transaction in the interdealer market.

Because swap transactions use dealers’ capital, dealers include a profit margin adjustment
to the mid-market valuation to reflect compensation for the use of funding (cost of capital).
Other adjustments include administrative and other costs, and liquidity adjustments. For some
exotic or infrequently traded derivatives, mid-market pricing overstates the value of these
assets. A dealer will adjust the pricing to compensate for the lack of liquidity of the assets.

V. Conclusions
This paper presents an overview of the economics of swaps and the market they trade in.
Taking recent municipal swap litigation as a starting point, we have also analyzed some of the
risk-return trade-offs that users of swaps face.

In choosing between alternative financing and swap options, economic decision rules should
be based on the minimization of the present value of interest costs subject to risk management
considerations like balance sheet gaps between assets and liabilities and cash flow hedging
needs. As with other risky assets, the benefits from using swaps are, at least in part,
compensation for bearing certain risks, like the risk of a rating downgrade, a default, and
basis risk.

Determining the appropriate value of a swap at any point in time is clearly crucial in making the
right decisions. We have reviewed and motivated the main pricing approach, the mid-market
model, and the main adjustments to this model, particularly credit risk. The adjustments should
rely on sound economic models, and the models should make appropriate risk adjustments to
expected losses and expected defaults.

www.nera.com 15
Notes

1 Special thanks to Lucy Allen, Jonah Bernstein, Renzo Comolli, 23 “AlabamaCounty Won’t Pledge $184 Million for Swaps (Update3),”
James Overdahl, and Vivienne Zhao for many helpful comments. Bloomberg, 6 March 2008.
Vivienne Zhao also provided outstanding research assistance. 24 “Alabama group files suit over Jefferson County debt,” Reuters,
2 Financial derivatives originated in their basic form in the Middle Ages, 5 September 2008; “JPMorgan, 11 Others Sued Over Jefferson County
with the need to mitigate some of the risks involved with maritime Crisis (Update),” Bloomberg, 17 June 2008.
merchants. One of the first contracts was the sea loan, an attempt to 25 “JP
Morgan, Facing Federal Probe, Exits Municipal Swaps (Update 3),”
trade casualty risk. See Meir Kohn, Risk Instruments in the Medieval
Bloomberg.com, 4 September 2008.
and Early Modern Economy, mimeo, Dartmouth College, 1999.
26 “Derivati:
Indagini in corso su 53 enti,” ilSole24Ore.com, 1 September
3 As explained below, the notional principal is used to calculate periodic
2010; “Impossible to Understand Swap Burns 290-Person Italian
swap payments, but does not actually changes hands. BIS statistics
Hamlet,” Bloomberg, 19 June 2009.
available at http://www.bis.org/statistics/derstats.htm.
27 Accordingto the Ministry of Economy and Finance data, see
4 Statistics available at http://www.isda.org/.
“Ma I radar del Tesoro non segnalano allarmi,” ilSole24Ore.com,
5 “Speech by SEC Chairman: Remarks at Investment Company Institute 1 September 2010.
2010 General Membership Meeting,” Dow Jones Newswire, 28 Banca d’Italia, “Local Government Debt,” Supplements to the
7 May 2010.
Statistical Bulletin, Volume XX, 29 October 2010.
6 The fixed-rate payer is said to have a long position in the (floating- 29 “Quattrobanche rinviate a giudizio per i derivati al comune di
to-fixed) swap, while the floating-rate payer is said to have a short
Milano,” Il Sole 24 Ore, 17 March 2010.
position in the swap.
30 “Quattrobanche rinviate a giudizio per i derivati al comune di
7 LIBOR is short for London Interbank Offered Rate, the rate published
Milano,” Ibid.
by the British Bankers’ Association. It represents an average rate at
which a financial institution is prepared to make a deposit with other 31 “L’inchiesta sui derivati di Roma,” Sole 24 Ore, 1 September 2010.
AA-rated banks. 32 InMilan, the allegation of excessive profits is that the banks have
8 We use LIBOR throughout to simplify exposition. But swaps may use charged “commissioni occulte,” i.e., hidden fees at inception, similar
other reference rates, like Treasury rates, commercial paper rates, etc. to the Erie City School District case.
These payoffs assume that the parties will perform on their payments. 33 “Interest
rate swaps—law lags behind financiers,” Law Society
Credit risk adjustments are discussed in Section IV.G. Because the
Gazette, 8 November 1989.
principal in a swap is not exchanged at maturity, it is termed notional
and is only used to calculate the periodic payments. 34 “British Curb On Rate Swaps,” New York Times, 23 February 1990.
9 We are abstracting from basis risk here. As we’ll see below, basis risk 35 See Titman, S., “Interest Rate Swaps and Corporate Financing
and other risks can interfere with this mechanism, and so even with Choices,” The Journal of Finance, Vol XLVII, 1992, for a theoretical
falling rates, a variable rate issuer can find themselves with increased justification of swaps.
variable liabilities. 36 SeeMeir Kohn, Financial Institutions and Markets, Second Edition,
10 Technically, using interest rate swaps, a company can change the Oxford University Press, 2004.
duration of its assets and liabilities to obtain a desired exposure to 37 This
interest rates. is simply an application of David Ricardo’s comparative advantage
principle to trading in risk. See for example, Bicksler and Chen,
11 Chu, Eric H., et al., “Interest Rate Swaps and Their Application “An Economic Analysis of Interest Rate Swaps,” Journal of Finance,
to Tax-Exempt Financing,” in Handbook of Municipal Bonds, Vol. 41, Issue 3, 1986: 645-655; and Meir Kohn, Financial Institutions
Fabozzi & Feldstein editors, Wiley, 2008, p. 313. and Markets, Second Edition, Oxford University Press, 2004.
12 Report on Transactions in Municipal Securities, Office of Economic 38 See,for example, Marcia Stigum, Stigum’s Money Market, Fourth
Analysis, United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Edition, McGraw-Hill, 2004; and Bicksler and Chen, “An Economic
1 July 2004. Analysis of Interest Rate Swaps,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 41, Issue 3,
13 Ibid. 1986: 645-655.
39 Other rates are short-term treasury rates, commercial paper rates,
14 Chu, Eric H., et al., “Interest Rate Swaps and Their Application
the SIFMA rate, etc.
to Tax-Exempt Financing,” in Handbook of Municipal Bonds,
Fabozzi & Feldstein editors, Wiley, 2008, p. 313. 40 The yield curve is a chart of interest rates as a function of the maturity
15 “Speech of the underlying bonds.
by SEC Chairman: Remarks at Investment Company Institute
2010 General Membership Meeting,” Dow Jones Newswire, 41 Thatis, long-term rates increase more than short-term rates. In
7 May 2010. contrast, the value of the swap will decrease over time if the yield
16 “Interest-Rate curve remains unchanged (and upward sloping). See, for example,
Deals Sting Cities, States,” Wall Street Journal,
Jorion, Philippe, Financial Risk Manager Handbook, Fifth Edition,
22 March 2010.
Wiley Finance, 2009.
17 “Alabama Schools to Skip Payment on JPMorgan Swap Deal 42 See,for example, Hull, J., Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives,
(Update2),” Bloomberg, 8 April 2009.
7th Edition, 2008; or Bank One Corporation v. Commissioner of
18 The swap has a negative value to the city. Interest-Rate Deals Sting Internal Revenue, 120 T.C. No. 11, 2 May 2003, p. 52.
Cities, States,” Wall Street Journal, 22 March 2010. 43 Seealso ISDA, “The Value of a New Swap,” ISDA Research Notes,
19 “Alabama Schools to Skip Payment on JPMorgan Swap Deal Issue 3, 2010, for a description of mid-market pricing and more details
(Update2)”, Bloomberg, 8 April 2009. about some of the costs.
20 “Judge OKs Deal in Alabama, JPMorgan Swaption Suit,” Bloomberg, 44 ISDA “The Value of a New Swap,” ISDA Research Notes,
27 December 2010. Issue 3, 2010.
21 “Speech by SEC Chairman: Remarks at Investment Company Institute 45 See ISDA, ISDA Margin Survey 2010, International Swaps and
2010 General Membership Meeting,” Dow Jones Newswire, Derivatives Association, 2010, for statistics about usage of
7 May 2010. collateralization. According to the ISDA Margin Survey 2010, 84% of
22 Ibid. fixed-income derivatives trades are subject to collateral arrangements.

www.nera.com 16
About NERA
NERA Economic Consulting (www.nera.com) is a global firm of experts dedicated to applying
economic, finance, and quantitative principles to complex business and legal challenges. For half
a century, NERA’s economists have been creating strategies, studies, reports, expert testimony,
and policy recommendations for government authorities and the world’s leading law firms and
corporations. We bring academic rigor, objectivity, and real world industry experience to bear
on issues arising from competition, regulation, public policy, strategy, finance, and litigation.

NERA’s clients value our ability to apply and communicate state-of-the-art approaches clearly
and convincingly, our commitment to deliver unbiased findings, and our reputation for quality
and independence. Our clients rely on the integrity and skills of our unparalleled team of
economists and other experts backed by the resources and reliability of one of the world’s
largest economic consultancies. With its main office in New York City, NERA serves clients from
more than 20 offices across North America, Europe, and Asia Pacific.

Contact
For further information and questions, please contact the author:

Dr. Massimiliano De Santis


Senior Consultant
+1 212 345 8055
massimiliano.desantis@nera.com

The opinions expressed herein do not necessarily represent the views of NERA Economic Consulting or any other
NERA consultant. Please do not cite without explicit permission from the author.

También podría gustarte